Income Distribution and Housing Expenses in Flanders and the Netherlands

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Income Distribution and Housing Expenses in Flanders and the Netherlands"

Transcription

1 Income Distribution and Housing Expenses in Flanders and the Netherlands Paper to be presented at the ISA International Housing Conference in Glasgow August 2009 Kristof Heylen & Marietta Haffner Kristof Heylen, Higher Institute for Labour Studies (HIVA), Catholic University of Leuven, Parkstraat 47, 3000 Leuven, Tel , Marietta Haffner, TU Delft, OTB Research Institute for Housing, Urban and Mobility Studies, Jaffalaan 9, 2628 BX Delft, , Income Distribution and Housing Expenses in Flanders and the Netherlands 1

2 Abstract This study explores the role of housing in income inequality and poverty in Flanders (northern part of Belgium) and the Netherlands in It analyses the distribution of disposable income before and after housing expenses by comparing disposable income with equivalent residual income. The Gini coefficient was used to measure income inequality, wile a poverty threshold was set at 50% of the median equivalent income. The most significant conclusion is that income inequality and poverty increase in both countries when equivalent disposable income is corrected for housing expenses. The results for Flanders and the Netherlands differ according to tenure. In the Netherlands, after deduction of housing expenses, the rise in poverty rate and income inequality was found to be greater among homeowners than among tenants, whereas in Flanders the opposite applied. In both countries the percentage of owner-occupiers on or below the poverty threshold, after deduction of housing expenses, was lower for outright homeowners. The housing allowance, which is generally granted to low-income households in the rental sector, plays a greater role as a subsidy mechanism in the Netherlands than in Flanders. Accordingly, the inequality gap after deduction of housing expenses turned out to be relatively small in the Netherlands compared with Flanders. In the case of tax benefits stemming from, say, mortgage interest relief the situation was reversed, i.e. the inequality gap was wider in the Netherlands than in Flanders. These conclusions also applied to the households on or below the poverty threshold. Key words: income inequality, poverty, housing, Flanders, the Netherlands 1. Introduction National and regional governments need clear insight into income distribution. This not only provides policymakers with a current picture of income inequality, it can also help them to judge the effectiveness of the wealth redistribution policy, which normally operates via the tax and social system. Secondly, a clearer understanding of the size of the group living on and below the poverty line provides an idea of the relative prosperity at the lower end of the income ladder. International 2

3 analyses enable wealth redistribution policies to be assessed across a broad geographical and temporal spectrum, but they can only be truly meaningful if the methodology is consistent. Income distribution in society is usually measured in terms of the income that remains after deduction of tax and social insurance contributions and the addition of supplementary payments, such as child benefit. This approach delivers a picture of living standards on the basis of household expenditure on consumer goods and services. In this paper we focus primarily on the role of the housing situation expenditure on a rented or owner-occupied dwelling, calculated with the housing expenses concept in income distribution. Needless to say, outright homeowners are in a far more advantageous position than tenants and mortgagors as they no longer have to cope with possibly high monthly housing costs. Tenants in the social rented sector are also at an advantage if they pay below-market rents. Studies that analyse only disposable income take no account of these advantages. This is why our study is based on after-housing expenses or residual income. We used two indicators to sketch out the relationship between income distribution and the housing situation: one for income inequality and one for poverty. The aim of this study was therefore, first of all, to show clearly how and the extent to which income inequality and poverty figures are influenced by the housing situation. For instance, what do poverty and income inequality mean in the context of tenancy or owner-occupation? We also examined the role of the in the expenditure approach visible subsidy mechanisms housing allowances and mortgage interest relief in income inequality. It should be noted that these mechanisms relate to only part of the government subsidy system, viz. the housing cash flows to and from households. A different approach would be needed for a full picture of the redistribution of government resources in matters of housing policy. Tenure distribution, which is partly determined by institutional factors, differs significantly from country to country. So, to ensure consistency in comparative international analyses, it is essential to correct disposable income for housing (Fahey, 2004; Ritakallio, 2003). The comparison between Flanders and the Netherlands the second aim of this study is an interesting case in point, given the striking differences in the housing profile, particularly in the organisation of the sectors of the housing market. At the end of the twentieth century a large ownership sector emerged in Flanders. From a European perspective the private rental sector in Flanders is medium-sized and the social rental sector is small. In the Netherlands, on the other hand, the owner-occupier sector, though the largest sector in the housing market, is fairly average by European standards. The Netherlands has the largest social rental sector in the world and a small private rental sector. This study elaborates on research by Heylen & Haffner (2008) which was conducted under the auspices of Steunpunt Ruimte en Wonen (space and housing research centre), an initiative of the Ministry of the Flemish Community. 3

4 We begin by explaining why we opted for an approach based on after-housing-costs or residual income. We then discuss the application of the concepts of residual income, income inequality and poverty indicator. In the third section we address the ownership sectors, and in the fourth, the housing policy situation in Flanders and the Netherlands. The paper ends with outcomes and conclusions. 2. Housing in relation to income distribution and poverty There is no standard international method (like the National Accounts which calculates national income) to assess income distribution in society at specific moments or over periods of time. Various choices need to be made (Smeeding, 2000). First, one has to decide whether to measure income or consumption and whether or not to include direct and indirect subsidies. A choice always has to be made in the distribution of disposable income across households or persons. Some authors, such as Krueger & Perri (2002), regard consumption as a better indicator than income for inequality and living standards, the idea being that income volatility at least in theory is ironed out via the capital market, thereby leading to even consumption through time. Other authors (Smeeding et al., 1993; Gardiner et al., 1995) argue that the results of research based on the relative distribution of disposable household income may be misleading since living standards are also influenced by non-cash or in-kind benefits or income from housing, education, childcare and healthcare. There are two ways to take account of the role these provisions play, e.g. benefits from housing in the household income (Frick & Grabka, 2003; Gardiner et al., 1995; Saunders & Siminski, 2005; Fahey, 2004; Ritakallio, 2003). First, non-cash income can be added to the disposable income. Ownership of a home constitutes noncash income for owner-occupiers while below-market rents constitute non-cash income for tenants in the social rental sector. Omission of this non-cash housing income can distort the results of comparisons of income at national and international level. The national standard of living will be affected if, for example, the higher income groups profit more, in relative terms, from in-kind income. There is absolutely no reason to assume that in-kind income is distributed in the same way as disposable income in any part of society. Non-cash income can be measured by an economic concept known as comprehensive income. When applied to housing, comprehensive income embraces the disposable cash income from, say, earnings as well as the non-cash or in-kind income that owner-occupiers enjoy by virtue of the fact that they pay no rent. In-kind income for owner-occupiers can be calculated by, for example, fixing an imputed rent, by converting home equity into an annuity flow, or by calculating the user costs of capital for the home (Van den Bosch, 1998; Chotikapanich et al., 2003; Gardiner et al., 1995). Imputed rent is calculated on the basis of the commercial rent that would be paid for an identical dwelling on the private rental market minus repair and maintenance costs. A fictitious annuity is calculated by making 4

5 assumptions about interest rates and the remaining lifespan of the dwelling. It is important when applying comprehensive income to take account of appreciation in the value of the dwelling, as this will contribute to changes in the future consumption options of the owners. In the case of tenants living in a social dwelling or a dwelling with a below-market rent the difference between the paid rent and the market rent is added to the income. Comprehensive income also includes personal subsidies. Finally, user costs of capital are also based on comprehensive income and are expressed as a return on equity that is invested in the home (Haffner, 1999; Yates, 1994). The second method is to convert non-cash income to lower household expenditure on housing consumption. Again, the favourable position of outright owners springs to mind (Van den Bosch & Van Dam, 2001). Homeowners with a paid-up mortgage will enjoy a better standard of living than mortgagors and tenants, assuming they all start out with equal incomes in the first place. This similarly applies albeit to a slightly lesser extent to tenants who pay a subsidised rent in the social rental sector. In this method housing expenses make a more or less fixed claim on the income a state of affairs that is not infrequently used to justify a different approach to expenditure on housing than expenditure on, say, food and clothing. A privately owned home is regarded as a sort of insurance against poverty at a later age. The principle is similar to that of a statutory company or private pension: people make investments (contributions) during their active life and enjoy the returns during retirement (Ritakallio, 2003). The approach in which housing expenses are deducted from disposable income ( before-housing-cost income ) is called after-housing-cost income. It is used in the UK (Atkinson, 1993; Johnson & Webb, 1992; DSS, 1993) and Australia (Harding & Szukalska, 2000; Harding et al, 2001) to measure poverty, but it is also used to measure income inequality (Ritakallio, 2003; Dewilde & Raeymaeckers, 2008; Van Dam et al., (2002), De Decker et al., (2008)). In this approach the rent is deducted from the disposable income of tenants and the mortgage interest and repayments are deducted from the disposable income of homeowners. This makes it easier to compare the income situation of mortgagors with the income situation of outright homeowners. It may be assumed that outright homeowners will have more disposable income in relative terms than mortgagors. This approach also takes implicit account of in-kind subsidies for social housing in the income distribution, so that the situation of private tenants can be compared with the situation of social tenants with below-market rents. Subject-based housing allowances are also comparable with the principle of a social rent (Gardiner et al., 1995). Though the purpose of both of these approaches can be the same to paint a picture of income before and after housing costs the way in which they are applied has an effect on the outcomes. Comprehensive income is generally higher than residual income (amounts are added to the disposable income). Though it shows the potential cash and non-cash income at a household s disposal, it does 5

6 not show what families actually spend. Hence, it maps out the risks for owner-occupiers as investors as opposed to tenants. Changes in the value of the dwelling (equity) will cause changes in comprehensive income, while the mortgage interest and repayments and the residual income remain the same. Ritakallio (2003) argues that adding the full imputed rent to the income creates a risk that the standard of living of mortgagors will be overestimated. They do, after all, face considerable housing expenses as they still have to pay off a loan. Neither potential income nor residual income can indicate whether households run into problems when financing other consumption. A poverty indicator will be a way to provide clarification. 3. Applying the concepts of residual income and inequality Our study revolves around income before and after housing expenses because the required data are readily available. We regard homeownership as a source of expenditure rather than a source of income. In doing that in the correction for the housing situation we do not take account of the quality of the dwellings or the preferences of households. Hence, we cannot distinguish between families that have a relatively low residual income because they choose to spend a large part of their income on a dwelling and families who have a low residual income simply because they have a low disposable income. Nor can we ascertain whether families with the same composition enjoy different housing comfort in exchange for the same residual income (Gardiner et al., 1995; Ritakallio, 2003; Thalmann, 2003). When we compare different sectors of the housing market, we do however know that there are differences in the quality of dwellings. Recent research has shown that, in Flanders, external structural quality, physical condition and level of comfort are significantly lower in the private than in the social rental sector. The privately owned dwellings score, on average, the highest on these counts. But there are also clear differences in quality and comfort in the homeownership sector itself (Heylen at al., 2007). This also applies to the Netherlands (Meijer & Thomsen, 2006). The highest average repair costs in 2000 were run up by pre-war single-family dwellings in the owner-occupier sector and pre-war private rental dwellings. Most of the problems relating to the state of the dwelling occurred in pre-war private rental housing, but the differences were small compared with similar dwellings in other sectors. No great differences in comfort were found between social and private rented dwellings (Haffner et al., 2009). There were more dwellings of relatively low and relatively high quality in the private rental sector than in the social rental sector. Our approach does not take account of these differences in comfort. Another shortcoming in the before- and after-housing-cost approach is that, if two or more countries are being compared, a problem may emerge regarding the way in which dwellings are financed. In some regions, e.g. Southern Europe, people resort far less to debt capital (mortgages) to finance 6

7 homeownership. The proportion of outright homeowners is over 60% in Greece, Italy and Spain and below 30% in France, the UK and Germany (Dol & Haffner, 2001). In Flanders and the Netherlands the figure is 41% and 7% respectively. Fahey (2004) maintains that the mortgage payment burden does not present a clear picture of the percentage of available resources that is spent on the purchase of the home Applying the concept of housing expenses and residual income Before we can determine residual income we need to define disposal income. In this study disposable income is the average monthly household income that remains after deduction of tax and social insurance contributions and the addition of any income-replacement, supplementary social insurance benefits and welfare payments. Table 1 shows the different constituents of residual income: housing expenses, visible state support for housing, and disposable household income. In the rental sector gross housing expenses consist of the gross rent. The net rent is calculated by deducting any housing allowance. In the owner-occupier sector net housing expenses are determined by the mortgage burden, which consists of interest payments including tax relief (1), mortgage repayments and/or endowment premiums. To maximise comparability the extra costs that a landlord incorporates in the rent are included in the gross housing expenses of the owner-occupier. Typical examples are building insurance (the Netherlands), the owner s share of maintenance, ground rent (the Netherlands), and the property tax that the owner pays (Flanders and the Netherlands). The residual income is calculated by deducting the net rent or net housing expenses from the disposable household income. Table 1: Composition of after-housing costs* income for tenants and owner-occupiers 1 Tenant Owner-occupier Gross rent** Gross housing expenses*** - Housing allowances - Fiscal effect = Net rent = Net housing expenses Disposable income Disposable income - Net rent - Net housing expenses = Residual income = Residual income See Appendix 1 for a breakdown of the items. *) Technically this concept should be called income after housing-expenses income, as it relates to expenses that are not necessarily economic costs, i.e. offers expressed in cash terms. **) Gross rent includes any costs that the landlord incorporates in the rent, such as maintenance, property tax, etc. Gross rent could be set lower than the market rent as a result of subsidy, rent regulation or acceptance of a loss (social landlord). ***) Gross housing expenses include the amounts required to finance the dwelling, property tax and other homeowner expenses, such as insurance, ground lease and the owner s share of maintenance. 7

8 In order to facilitate comparisons between different types of households, disposable income and residual income were corrected for household size on the basis of the OECD equivalence scale. Though the OECD scale is basically designed for corrections to disposable household income, we used it also to correct residual income because there was no better alternative. One may, however, safely assume that housing offers greater economies of scale than many other goods and services. For example, every household needs a bathroom whether it is used by the whole family or only one person. A correction performed with the OECD scale therefore results in an underestimation of the residual equivalent income. Finally, it is important to remember that the concept of housing expenses was applied to cash flows that households need to generate in order to fund their housing consumption, minus direct (housing allowance) or indirect (mortgage interest relief) state support. The lowering of the gross housing expenses was treated in the analysis as a tax benefit or as fiscal support for owner-occupiers. This approach also takes account of implicit subsidies, but it cannot distinguish them as in the case of, benefits, allowances etc. (Haffner, 1999) Application of the concepts of income inequality and poverty Income inequality was mapped out with the Gini coefficient, the most commonly used method for measuring income inequality. The Gini coefficient can be graphically interpreted with the aid of the Lorenz curve. The value always lies between 0 and 1, in which 0 stands for total equality and 1 stands for total inequality. The higher the Gini value, the greater the income inequality. The numerator is the sum of the absolute values of the income differences between individual households and all other households. This sum is divided by 2, because the income difference between every two households is calculated twice (2). The numerator a dispersion measure is also divided by the average income, thus making the Gini coefficient scale-independent. As a result, the Gini value remains the same whenever an income is multiplied by a constant. Scale-independence is regarded as an essential factor in obtaining an accurate measure of independence (Allison, 1978). The Gini coefficient was preferred above other popular methods for measuring inequality such as the 80/20 ratio and the relative interquartile range (3), because the first covers the entire population whereas the other two cover only a part thereof (Allison, 1978; van den Brakel-Hofmans, 2007; see also Frick & Grabka, 2003). We used the 50% norm for the poverty threshold. This norm is used in many poverty studies (Saunders et al., 2002; Harding et al., 2001). A household is deemed to live in poverty if its equivalent income is lower than 50% of the median equivalent income. This definition is in line with the Eurostat norm, which is used in the EU to monitor poverty and compare countries. According to 8

9 the Eurostat norm, families are at risk of poverty when the equivalent income is lower than 60% of the median income Databases We used the Housing Survey 2005 of the Kenniscentrum voor Duurzaam Woonbeleid (knowledge centre for sustainable housing policy) to calculate the distribution and poverty measures for Flanders. This survey covers 5,216 Flemish households. A weighting factor was applied for the distribution of dwelling types and districts. If the housing market is split according to tenure, the numbers are still high enough to deliver accurate and reliable results. For the Netherlands we used the WoON 2006 Housing Survey, conducted by the Department of Housing. The income data from the tax records for 2005 were linked to the survey data. About 64,000 households were interviewed, approximately 54,000 of whom lived in independent units (4). Weighting factors were applied to the sample to obtain results for all Dutch households (almost seven million). 4. Sectors of the housing market Before we discuss housing policy relevant to housing expenses, we shall take a brief look at some trends in the homeownership sector in Flanders and the Netherlands. In 2005 the tenure in almost three out of every four Flemish households was owner-occupier, reflecting a distinct upward trend. In % of households were owner-occupiers. By 2001 this figure had risen to 73%. At the same time, 18.5% of Flemish households lived in the private rental sector and 5.6% in the by European standards small social rental sector. Compared with 2001 the social rental sector was growing and the private rental sector was shrinking accordingly. In 2006 the owner-occupier sector, with a market share of almost 56% was the largest sector in the Netherlands (see Elsinga et al, 2007). The rental sector was dominated by social landlords, the housing associations, whose market share dropped from almost 37% in 2002 to just over 35% in Dutch housing associations are private government-sanctioned institutions with a social remit, viz.: to provide affordable housing for households with limited means. The private rental sector, which dominated the housing market in the first half of the twentieth century, has become the smallest sector in 2006, with a market share of 9%. The main players in this sector are small private landlords offering cheap dwellings and institutional investors offering expensive dwellings. Figure 1 shows the distribution of the income groups in the housing market sectors according to tertiles of equivalent disposable income. In the case of Flanders outright homeowners are 9

10 overrepresented in the first tertile. This might be explained by the fact that 61% of the people in this group are retired. As might be expected, the largest proportion of social tenants is in the first tertile. Private tenants are more or less equally spread across all three tertiles and mortgagors are clearly in the majority in the third. In the Netherlands mortgagors, at 71%, are also overrepresented in the third tertile, while the spread for private tenants, at around ten percent, is more or less even. The percentage of mortgagors is higher in all tertiles for the Netherlands than for Flanders. The situation is entirely different for outright homeowners with an even spread of between six and eight percent in the Netherlands as opposed to a steady decline in Flanders. As in Flanders, households in the social rental sector are overrepresented in the first tertile. The share is lower in the second tertile, but it still stands at a substantial thirteen percent in the third. Hence even in the third tertile there are more tenants in the social sector than in the private sector. Figure 1 Housing market sectors (in %) according to tertiles of equivalent income in Flanders (2005) and the Netherlands (2006) 100% 80% 60% 40% Outright homeowners Mortgagers Social rental sector Private rental sector 20% 0% Tertile 1 Tertile 2 Tertile 3 Total Tertile 1 Tertile 2 Tertile 3 Total Flanders The Netherlands Source: Housing Survey 2005; WoON 2006/ OTB Research Institute calculations 5. Housing expenses policy Housing expenses are largely determined by government policy. We shall now turn our attention to the relevant housing policy instruments in each country. 10

11 5.1. Flanders The primary aim of housing policy in Belgium which dates from the end of the 19th century is to encourage homeownership (Goossens, 1997; Deschamps, 1997). When responsibility for most of the housing policy was transferred from federal to regional (Flemish) level in the 1990 s, a shift occurred in favour of the rental sector. However the federal government still retained important fiscal powers for supporting homeownership (Winters et al., 2007). Mortgages taken out before 2005 fall under the old tax system, dating from 1 January The tax benefits derived from this system may be made up of different constituents, which are determined by certain circumstances and are limited by ceilings. The old system is fairly complicated compared with the new one, which became effective in the tax year 2005 and in which the housing bonus is a flatrate. All in all, the tax benefits are positively related to the size of the mortgage (De Meyer, 2007). The federal government is also responsible for the housing legislation. In contrast with the Netherlands, Belgium has no system for setting rents in the private sector: the landlord is free to set the rent. During the contract period the rent can only be raised accordng to the price index development (Federal Department of Justice, Federale Overheidsdienst Justitie, 2008). In 2005 the social rental sector was the responsibility of Flanders. The current calculations for rent setting and adjustments in the social sector include a link to both quality and affordability. As it costs low-income households much less to rent a dwelling in the social rental sector than in the commercial sector, a subsidy system appears to be in place (Winters et al, 2007). Also, there was a selective system of housing allowances in Flanders in 2005, which targeted a few low-income households and households that moved from unhealthy or overcrowded accommodation to an adequate dwelling (Keulen, 2006). The Housing Survey of 2005 revealed that, in effect, only 2% of tenants were receiving housing allowance (Heylen et al., 2007) The Netherlands Table 1 shows that the different components of housing expenses are influenced at different points. For the tenant this happens at the level of gross rent. In the Netherlands ninety-five percent of rents are regulated by the government. Landlords can fix the rent within certain limits. Social landlords usually set the rent of new-builds with a lower-than-market return on investment (Elsinga et al., 2007; Haffner & Elsinga, 2007; Winters et al., 2007, Ouwehand & van Daalen, 2002). These influences on gross rent, which may be regarded as an implicit subsidy, are not explicitly incorporated in our approach. The tenant s subsidy, which does actually figure in the housing expenses, is the housing allowance which was introduced across the entire rental sector in 1975 (Elsinga et al., 2007) with the primary purpose of making rental housing affordable. A second aim the prevention of social segregation 11

12 was added in The size of the housing allowance is determined by the income, the rent (maximum of euros per month in 2006) and the composition of the household. In 2006 one out of three tenants was receiving housing allowance. The overall average was 148 euros per month (Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning & the Environment (Ministerie van VROM), 2007). Gross housing expenses in the owner-occupier sector in the Netherlands are dictated principally by the mortgage burden. Most private homes are financed by a thirty-year mortgage with a fixed period of interest (see also Neuteboom, 2002). In recent years, new types of mortgages whereby capital is not redeemed have gained in popularity; at the most, sums of money are set aside in a savings or investment account (endowment mortgages, investment mortgages, interest-only mortgages). Home buyers may also take out mortgages worth 125% of the forced-sale value of the property (5). As the interest is tax-deductible for thirty years, the system, in effect, encourages people to take out interest-only mortgages (Haffner, 2002). This benefit is marginally offset by a tax on imputed rent amounting to less than one percent of the market value of the property in unoccupied state. Since 2005 the tax on imputed rent has been maximised to the amount of deductible interest. This means that when the mortgage is repaid, the owner-occupier is no longer liable for tax on imputed rent. The fiscal effect is included as a separate item in the housing expenses in Table Income distribution 2005/6, before and after housing expenses 6.1. Housing expenses and income according to housing market sectors Before we explore the effect of the housing situation on income distribution, we shall look at housing expenses and disposable and residual incomes in the different sectors of the housing market. We shall show that there are clear differences between Flanders and the Netherlands in this area. Table 2 shows that the average gross rent in Flanders is much higher in the private sector (435 euros) than in the social rental sector (261 euros) with a split of approximately When we compare the number of rooms including kitchens and bathrooms we find no significant differences. So, the difference in rent cannot be explained by differences in the size of dwellings in terms of the number of rooms. The difference is therefore largely attributable to the subsidy granted to social tenants. In both the private and the social rental sector in Flanders the average subject-based housing allowance is no more than one euro. As mentioned earlier, the range of the housing allowance system in Flanders is very limited. The maximum official housing allowance was euros in 2005 and, as such, is in line with the figures in the Housing Survey for The average housing allowance in 2005 was 121 euros per recipient. The equivalent disposable income was, on average, 345 euros 12

13 higher in the private rental sector than in the social rental sector, but the gap narrows down to 247 euros when we factor in the housing expenses and therefore the social rent subsidies. The average gross housing expenses for mortgagors amounted to 549 euros. This works out at an average of 468 euros after deduction of mortgage interest relief. As mentioned previously, outright homeowners are in a favourable position as far as housing expenses are concerned. In Flanders they only need to pay maintenance and property tax, which averages out at 90 euros. As there is a relatively large percentage of retired people in this group, the average equivalent income is significantly lower than that of mortgagors. The differences between the two countries lie in the fiscal effect and by association the gross housing expenses. In Flanders, the monthly tax benefit is limited to an average of 81 euros, but in the Netherlands it can mount to as much as 200 euros. However, the higher tax effect in the Netherlands is offset by a higher average mortgage payment burden than in Flanders (300 euros difference). Net housing expenses in the Netherlands are therefore, on average, around 200 euros higher than in Flanders. Hence, a higher tax advantage is no guarantee for lower housing expenses. 13

14 Table 2: Housing expenses and residual income according to tenure and landlord, averages in euros per month, Flanders/The Netherlands, 2005/2006 Gross housing expenses Housing allowance/ tax relief Net rent or expenses Equivalised disposable income Equivalised residual income Number of rooms* Flanders Rental sector Private Social Owner-occupier sector Mortgagor Outright owner Total households** Netherlands Rental sector Private Social Owner-occupier sector Mortgagor Outright owner 136 6*** Total households** 1: Average for the rental sector differs significantly from the average for the owner-occupier sector, T-test (á=0.05). 2 : Average for the private rental sector differs significantly from the average for the social rental sector, T-test (á=0.05). 3 : Average for mortgagors differs significantly from the average for outright owners, T-test (á=0.05) *: Two rooms have been added to the Dutch averages to take account of the bathroom and kitchen. The T-test was performed on non-enhanced averages, i.e. the numbers without bathroom and kitchen. **: Housing expenses are not shown for all households because the term has a different meaning for tenants and mortgagors (6). ***: Households that have just paid off the mortgage, so that a tax relief is still noted by the tax authorities. Source: Housing Survey 2005; WoON 2006/ OTB Research Institute calculations Secondly, the housing allowance system has a stronger effect in the Netherlands than in Flanders, amounting to an average supplement of 22 euros in the private sector and 53 euros in the social sector. The difference is due mainly to the difference in the number of recipients, given that the total average monthly amount per recipient is 121 euros in Flanders and 148 euros in the Netherlands (see above). 14

15 Finally, as at 1 January 2006, a number of results for the Netherlands can be compared with results for Flanders. To begin with, net rent in the Netherlands is significantly lower in the social rental sector than in the private rental sector, even though, at 85%, the gap is narrower than in Flanders. This finding cannot be explained by differences in the number of rooms between both countries. It is plausible though that some of the difference may be explained by differences in quality. When it comes to the higher average equivalent income, residual income in the Netherlands is also higher for private tenants (1,117 euros per month) than for social tenants (940 euros) Income inequality and poverty and the impact of the housing situation Flanders Table 3 shows the housing expenses, subsidies and (residual) income for Flanders, split according to housing market sector and income tertile. These tertiles were calculated separately for each sector on the basis of equivalent disposable income. The Gini coefficients are also shown to indicate income inequality before and after housing expenses. We can conclude from the table that inequality on the basis of equivalent disposable income in Flanders is highest for outright owners (Gini=0.259) and lowest for tenants in the social rental sector (Gini=0.172). These outcomes are in line with expectations. The income gap is not so wide in social housing because, in this sector, only families with incomes below a certain level are eligible for support. Income inequality is relatively high in the case of outright homeowners. This result is logical as 61% of heads of household are retired and have a lower income than before and 31% are still employed (Housing Survey). Recent studies of the private rental market have identified three segments: elderly people in good, recently built dwellings; young high-income households who are preparing for homeownership; and low-income families in older and poorer dwellings (Le Roy et al, 2008). Given the diversity in the income profiles of these groups, one might logically expect the Gini coefficient to be relatively higher for private tenants (0.23) than for social tenants (0.172). When housing expenses are deducted from disposable income, income inequality increases in each sector. The general Gini coefficient (for all households) rises from to 0.271, indicating that housing expenses, in general, place a heavier burden on the budgets of lower-income households, regardless of the housing market sector. In Flanders, after deduction of housing expenses, income inequality rises far more sharply for tenants than for owner-occupiers. The Gini value for the rental sector rises by 27% to 0.294, and for the owner-occupier sector, by a mere 5% to

16 Figure 1 offers an explanation for the limited rise in income inequality among owner-occupiers. Mortgagors with the greatest income correction have a strong income profile. Outright owners with only a small correction are overrepresented in the lowest tertile. It appears, on average, that more housing expenses are deducted in the transition to residual income for outright owners in higher income groups than for outright owners in lower-income groups. Even so, the Gini coefficient still rises by 5% because housing expenses make a deeper dent in the budget of lower-income households. The increase is most prominent for tenants in the private sector (32%). As rent in the social sector is determined by income, the rise is more limited for social tenants (21%). As one might expect, the Gini coefficient rises by 16% for mortgagors and by a more limited 7% for outright homeowners. The incorporation of subsidies in the analyses has little effect on income inequality for tenants (housing allowance) or homeowners with a mortgage (tax benefits) when considered separately. The incorporation of subsidies by deducting them from the housing expenses has little effect for tenants in the private and social rental sectors because, in absolute terms, there is very little variation in the income tertiles. Though the tax benefit increases considerably between the tertiles in absolute terms, it remains relatively even in relation to disposable income. The equivalent tax benefit amounts to, on average, 3.2%, 3.1% and 2.8% of the equivalent disposable income in the first, second and third tertile respectively. When all incomes are multiplied by more or less the same factor, the Gini value for income distribution remains virtually the same (scale independence) (Allison, 1978). As mortgagors are overrepresented in the higher income groups (see Figure 1), the tax relief enhances inequality for all households. Higher-income groups profit more from tax relief because they tend to buy or build more expensive dwellings. As mentioned earlier, until 2005, the level of tax relief was positively related to the size of the mortgage. It is still positively related to the marginal rate of income tax, which, of course, rises in accordance with the taxable income. 16

17 Table 3: Housing expenses, subsidies and income inequality before and after housing expenses, according to tenure and tertiles of equivalent income, averages in equivalent euros per month, Flanders, 2005 Gross housing expenses Housing allowances/ tax relief* Net rent or expenses Equivalised disposable income Equivalent residual income Private rent Gini coefficient % Social rent Gini coefficient % Rent total Gini coefficient % Owner-occupiers (mortgage holders) (32) (45) (60) Gini coefficient % Owner-occupiers (outright owners) Gini coefficient % Owner-occupier total Gini coefficient % All households Gini coefficient % Source: Housing Survey 2005; N all households=3,821 *: The average equivalent tax relief 17

18 The Netherlands Table 4 is the Dutch equivalent of Table 3. As in Flanders, and in line with expectations, inequality on the basis of equivalent disposable income is highest for outright homeowners (Gini=0.328) and lowest for tenants in the social rental sector (Gini=0.206). Again, as in Flanders, the Gini coefficient for private tenants, at 0.268, lies between the two. One contrast with Flanders is that the Gini coefficient for these groups is higher, indicating a greater diversity in income profiles within each group in the Netherlands. This applies to all households: the Gini coefficient for the Netherlands is compared with for Flanders. When we deduct the housing expenses from disposable income, we see that income inequality in the Netherlands as in Flanders increases in each sector of the housing market. The Gini coefficient for all households rises from to This increase is greater in the Netherlands than in Flanders in absolute and relative terms. The situation in terms of income inequality, before and after deduction of housing expenses, is the reverse of the situation in Flanders: income inequality in the Netherlands rises more sharply for owner-occupiers (23%) than for tenants (17%). Because the relationship between rent and income is stronger in the social sector than in the private rental sector, inequality rises more sharply for private tenants (21%) than for social tenants (17%). As there are fewer private tenants than social tenants, the average rise in inequality in the rental sector (see Figure 1) when housing is taken into account corresponds with the average increase in inequality in the social rental sector. In the owner-occupier sector the strongest increase in inequality occurs among the mortgagors (26%). Outright homeowners face only a limited increase in inequality (6%) because they no longer have a mortgage to pay. Given that this group is fairly limited in the Netherlands with very little variation across the tertiles (see Figure 1), the increase in inequality among all owner-occupiers is still considerable at 23%. The main differences between the Netherlands and Flanders lie in the rental sector. The percentual increase in the Gini values for the Netherlands are lower with the step towards residual income than in Flanders. A similar pattern appears in the social rental sector (17% compared with 21%). The housing allowance in the Netherlands is a levelling factor; as the housing allowance targets tenants from the lowest-income groups, the increase in income inequality will be softened in the rental sectors. Given the overrepresentation of tenants in the lowest tertile, it appears that the increase in income inequality is also softened the housing allowance system. 18

19 19

20 Table 4: Housing expenses, subsidies and income inequality before and after housing expenses, according to tenure and tertiles of equivalent income, averages in euros per month, The Netherlands, 2006 Gross housing expenses Housing allowances/ tax relief** Net rent or expenses Equivalent disposable income Equivalent residual income Private rent (40) (12) (1) Gini coefficient % Social rent (81) (35) (3) Gini coefficient % Rent total Gini coefficient % Owner-occupiers (mortgagors) (65) (115) (193) Gini coefficient % Owner-occupiers (outright owners)* Gini coefficient % Owner-occupier total Gini coefficient % All households Gini coefficient % *: Households which have just paid of the mortgage; so a tax relief is still noted by the tax authorities. **: Equivalent amounts for housing allowance and fiscal effect. Source: WoON 2008/OTB Research Institute calculations; total households (weighted): 6,800,576 20

21 For outright owners the increase of six or seven percent that occurs in the transition from disposable to residual income is more or less the same in both countries but the rise is still higher for mortgagors in the Netherlands (26%) than in Flanders (16%). Clearly, in the Netherlands, the tax benefits in both absolute and relative terms increase strongly with income. In contrast with Flanders, tax benefits enhance income inequality among mortgagors. After all, the equivalent tax benefit is, on average, 5.8% of the equivalent disposable income in the first tertile, compared with 6.9% in the third tertile. As mortgagors are overrepresented in the higher-income groups (Figure 1), the tax relief also enhances income inequality in general Poverty rate before and after deduction of housing expenses Table 5 shows that, when the poverty threshold is set at 50% of the median equivalent income, poverty increases sharply after deduction of housing expenses in both Flanders and the Netherlands. The relative increase is about the same in both cases, with an overall poverty rate of 14.9% for the Netherlands after housing expenses compared with 15.9% for Flanders. The results for the housing sectors correspond with the inequality analysis. Poverty in the private rental market in Flanders increases sharply (151%) after rent deductions. In the Netherlands the increase is much smaller (62%), partly because of the elaborate housing allowance system. The rise in poverty in respect of social housing is also more prominent in Flanders than the Netherlands. In contrast, the rise in poverty rate for mortgagors is relatively higher in the Netherlands than in Flanders (178% compared with 83%). We have already shown that, in the Netherlands, the fiscal benefit is absolutely and relatively higher in the highest income groups than in the lowest income groups. The tax benefit system increases not only inequality but income poverty as well. For Flanders, the tax benefit is relatively even spread across the income groups. Finally, a slight decrease occurs in the poverty rate for outright homeowners when residual income is taken into account. This is a logical result, given that the residual income of this group is also its disposable income and that the 50% poverty threshold is lower for residual income. 21

22 Table 5: Households in poverty* (in %), for equivalent income before and after (equivalent) housing expenses, Flanders/The Netherlands, 2005/2006 % in poverty % in poverty after housing Difference Flanders Total households % Rental sector % Private rental sector % Social rental sector % Owner-occupier sector % Mortgagors % Outright owners % The Netherlands Total households % Rental sector % Private rental sector % Social rental sector % Owner-occupier sector % Mortgagors % Outright owners % *: Poverty threshold is set at 50% of the median equivalent income Sources: Housing Survey 2005, WoON Conclusions It is essential to apply consistent indicators in international comparative analyses on income distribution. Disposable income, the standard approach in analyses of poverty and income inequality, ignores the fact that the consumption options, and hence the living standard of families, are also influenced by in-kind or non-cash provisions connected with the housing situation. These provisions can differ considerably from one country to another. In this study in-kind benefits were addressed by deducting housing expenses from disposable income, thus producing the after-housing-costs income or residual income. In such calculations outright homeowners no longer have housing expenses and therefore have a relatively higher income than mortgagors. The study also considered the situation of social tenants compared with private tenants in view of the fact that the rent for social tenants is below the commercial level. As a result, it was possible to draw a clearer comparison of the different 22

23 sectors in the housing market. This approach further facilitated comparisons by correcting for prominent differences in tenure between the countries. The aim of the study was to analyse how and to what extent the housing situation influences the income distribution, with specific emphasis on the subsidy mechanisms in housing policy. We decided to compare Flanders and the Netherlands, two countries with totally different housing policies and housing market sectors. Income inequality and poverty increase considerably in both countries when equivalent income is corrected for housing expenses. These increases imply that housing expenses place a heavier burden on the budget of lower-income groups than higher income groups. This result is in line with the findings of Fahey (2004), who conducted a European comparative study on the relationship between housing expenses and income poverty. It also emerged that income inequality in the rental and owner-occupied subsectors generally is higher in the Netherlands than in Flanders, for both disposable and residual income. Because of the relatively larger number of social tenants in the rental sector in the Netherlands, income inequality in the Dutch rental sector after taking housing expenses into account, however, turns out lower (0.26) than in Flanders (0.29). Furthermore, an increase in inequality after deduction of housing expenses was found in each sector of the housing market in both countries. This inequality increase is in absolute and relative terms - more prominent for Dutch mortgagors than for the Flemish ones. For tenants the effect is the other way around. In the Netherlands the rise in inequality was found to be greater among homeowners than among tenants, whereas in Flanders the opposite applies. The steeper rise in general inequality in the Netherlands is tied with the fact that there is a lower proportion of outright owners than in Flanders. The overrepresentation of outright owners in the first tertile in Flanders compensates for the deeper impact that housing expenses generally tend to make in the budgets of lower-income groups. As opposed to the inequality analysis, the share of people in poverty according to a relative poverty line of 50% of median disposable income is higher in Flanders (10.5%) than in The Netherlands (9.5%). Also in case of residual income, poverty is higher in Flanders. These results point out that a combination of both poverty and inequality measures can be illuminating. Despite a lower general inequality level, relative more households in Flanders appear to be on the bottom of the income distribution. As was argued before, it turns out that in both countries the share of poor outright owners is lower after deduction of housing expenses. For all other tenures the poverty rate increases with the step from disposable to residual income. 23

Kristof Heylen a b & Marietta Haffner b c d a Higher Institute for Labour (Hiva), Catholic University of Leuven,

Kristof Heylen a b & Marietta Haffner b c d a Higher Institute for Labour (Hiva), Catholic University of Leuven, This article was downloaded by: [KU Leuven University Library] On: 28 January 2015, At: 01:41 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office:

More information

Affordability of housing Flanders and the Netherlands compared in the short-term and long-term

Affordability of housing Flanders and the Netherlands compared in the short-term and long-term Affordability of housing Flanders and the Netherlands compared in the short-term and long-term Marietta Haffner 1 Kristof Heylen 2 1) OTB Research Institute for Housing, Urban and Mobility Studies, Delft

More information

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized International Comparison Program [03.01] User Cost Method Global Office 2 nd Regional

More information

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Completed by: Will Dunning Inc. For: Trinity Diversified North America Limited February 2009 Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Overview We are

More information

OECD-IMF WORKSHOP. Real Estate Price Indexes Paris, 6-7 November 2006

OECD-IMF WORKSHOP. Real Estate Price Indexes Paris, 6-7 November 2006 OECD-IMF WORKSHOP Real Estate Price Indexes Paris, 6-7 November 2006 Paper 18 Owner-occupied housing for the HICP Alexandre Makaronidis and Keith Hayes (Eurostat) D-4 Owner-Occupied Housing for the Harmonized

More information

Country Policy Framework Netherlands

Country Policy Framework Netherlands Promoting Investment in Private Rented Housing Supply: International Policy Comparisons Project for Communities and Local Government by: Centre for Comparative Housing Research De Montfort University,

More information

A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County

A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County Resilient Neighborhoods Technical Reports and White Papers Resilient Neighborhoods Initiative 5-2014 A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County Jiangping Zhou Iowa State University,

More information

Filling the Gaps: Active, Accessible, Diverse. Affordable and other housing markets in Johannesburg: September, 2012 DRAFT FOR REVIEW

Filling the Gaps: Active, Accessible, Diverse. Affordable and other housing markets in Johannesburg: September, 2012 DRAFT FOR REVIEW Affordable Land and Housing Data Centre Understanding the dynamics that shape the affordable land and housing market in South Africa. Filling the Gaps: Affordable and other housing markets in Johannesburg:

More information

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING Prepared for The Fair Rental Policy Organization of Ontario By Clayton Research Associates Limited October, 1993 EXECUTIVE

More information

Findings: City of Johannesburg

Findings: City of Johannesburg Findings: City of Johannesburg What s inside High-level Market Overview Housing Performance Index Affordability and the Housing Gap Leveraging Equity Understanding Housing Markets in Johannesburg, South

More information

A matter of choice? RSL rents and home ownership: a comparison of costs

A matter of choice? RSL rents and home ownership: a comparison of costs sector study 2 A matter of choice? RSL rents and home ownership: a comparison of costs Key findings and implications Registered social landlords (RSLs) across the country should monitor their rents in

More information

Sales Ratio: Alternative Calculation Methods

Sales Ratio: Alternative Calculation Methods For Discussion: Summary of proposals to amend State Board of Equalization sales ratio calculations June 3, 2010 One of the primary purposes of the sales ratio study is to measure how well assessors track

More information

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector Prepared for The Association of Residential Letting Agents & the ARLA Group of Buy to Let Mortgage Lenders ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector Fourth Quarter 2010 Prepared by: O M Carey Jones

More information

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers?

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? Dr Jens Mehrhoff*, Head of Section Business Cycle, Price and Property Market Statistics * Jens This Mehrhoff, presentation Deutsche

More information

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector Prepared for The Association of Residential Letting Agents ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector Second Quarter 2014 Prepared by: O M Carey Jones 5 Henshaw Lane Yeadon Leeds LS19 7RW June, 2014

More information

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary 2006 July www.calgary.ca Call 3-1-1 PUBLISHING INFORMATION TITLE: AUTHOR: STATUS: TRENDS IN AFFORDABLE HOME OWNERSHIP CORPORATE ECONOMICS FINAL PRINTING DATE:

More information

The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s.

The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s. The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s. The subject property was originally acquired by Michael and Bonnie Etta Mattiussi in August

More information

Impact of welfare reforms on housing associations: Early effects and responses by landlords and tenants

Impact of welfare reforms on housing associations: Early effects and responses by landlords and tenants Impact of welfare reforms on housing associations: Early effects and responses by landlords and tenants For the National Housing Federation February 2014 Legal notice 2014 Ipsos MORI all rights reserved.

More information

Appendix 1: Gisborne District Quarterly Market Indicators Report April National Policy Statement on Urban Development Capacity

Appendix 1: Gisborne District Quarterly Market Indicators Report April National Policy Statement on Urban Development Capacity Appendix 1: Gisborne District Quarterly Market Indicators Report April 2018 National Policy Statement on Urban Development Capacity Quarterly Market Indicators Report April 2018 1 Executive Summary This

More information

Analysing lessee financial statements and Non-GAAP performance measures

Analysing lessee financial statements and Non-GAAP performance measures February 2019 IFRS Foundation The Essentials Issue No. 5 Analysing lessee financial statements and Non-GAAP performance measures Introduction Investors and company managers generally view free cash flow

More information

Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to March 2018 All Residents Report April 2018

Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to March 2018 All Residents Report April 2018 Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to March 2018 All Residents Report April 2018 Executive summary This report summarises the results of the continuous STAR survey of Radian s residents,

More information

Is renting unaffordable in the Netherlands? 1

Is renting unaffordable in the Netherlands? 1 ENHR 2013 Conference Overcoming the crisis. Integrating the Urban Environment Is renting unaffordable in the Netherlands? 1 Authors: Marietta Haffner 1,2 and Harry Boumeester 1 1 OTB Research Institute

More information

Filling the Gaps: Stable, Available, Affordable. Affordable and other housing markets in Ekurhuleni: September, 2012 DRAFT FOR REVIEW

Filling the Gaps: Stable, Available, Affordable. Affordable and other housing markets in Ekurhuleni: September, 2012 DRAFT FOR REVIEW Affordable Land and Housing Data Centre Understanding the dynamics that shape the affordable land and housing market in South Africa. Filling the Gaps: Affordable and other housing markets in Ekurhuleni:

More information

IFRS - 3. Business Combinations. By:

IFRS - 3. Business Combinations. By: IFRS - 3 Business Combinations Objective 1. The purpose of this IFRS is to specify to disclose financial information by an entity when carrying out a business combination. In particular, specifies that

More information

The private rented housing sector: The UK and ideas from other countries

The private rented housing sector: The UK and ideas from other countries The private rented housing sector: The UK and ideas from other countries Social Market Foundation Seminar Thursday 23 rd March 2017 Professor Michael Oxley Director, Cambridge Centre for Housing Planning

More information

Performance of the Private Rental Market in Northern Ireland

Performance of the Private Rental Market in Northern Ireland Summary Research Report July - December Performance of the Private Rental Market in Northern Ireland Research Report July - December 1 Northern Ireland Rental Index: Issue No. 8 Disclaimer This report

More information

SUMMARY. Christian Donner THE END OF AUSTRIAN "WOHNBAUFÖRDERUNG" Outlines for a Comprehensive Housing Policy

SUMMARY. Christian Donner THE END OF AUSTRIAN WOHNBAUFÖRDERUNG Outlines for a Comprehensive Housing Policy SUMMARY Christian Donner THE END OF AUSTRIAN "WOHNBAUFÖRDERUNG" Outlines for a Comprehensive Housing Policy 1 Present Situation Austrian housing conditions correspond to those prevailing in highly developed

More information

Economic and monetary developments

Economic and monetary developments Box 4 House prices and the rent component of the HICP in the euro area According to the residential property price indicator, euro area house prices decreased by.% year on year in the first quarter of

More information

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore Joy Chan Yuen Yee & Liu Yunhua Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Nanyang Avenue, Singapore

More information

A Tale of Two Canadas

A Tale of Two Canadas Centre for Urban and Community Studies Research Bulletin #2 August 2001 A Tale of Two Canadas Homeowners Getting Richer, Renters Getting Poorer Income and Wealth Trends in Toronto, Montreal and Vancouver,

More information

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 29.11.2008 EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARD 3 Business combinations OBJECTIVE 1 The objective of this IFRS is to specify the financial reporting

More information

Sales of intermediate housing

Sales of intermediate housing Sales of intermediate housing - 2009 Summary of issues...1 20.1 Introduction... 2 20.2 Intermediate Housing who has been housed... 2 Table 1: Shared ownership and OMHomeBuy sales, 2007/08...3 Fig 1: Total

More information

Sector Scorecard. Proposed indicators for measuring efficiency within the sector have been developed for the following areas:

Sector Scorecard. Proposed indicators for measuring efficiency within the sector have been developed for the following areas: Registered Providers Working Group on Efficiency Sector Scorecard Proposed indicators for measuring efficiency within the sector have been developed for the following areas: A. Business Health B. Development

More information

Spring Budget Submission to HM Treasury From the Association of Residential Letting Agents (ARLA) January 2017

Spring Budget Submission to HM Treasury From the Association of Residential Letting Agents (ARLA) January 2017 Spring Budget Submission to HM Treasury From the Association of Residential Letting Agents (ARLA) January 2017 Background 1. ARLA is the UK s foremost professional and regulatory body for letting agents;

More information

An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria through the Lens of Fundamentals

An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria through the Lens of Fundamentals An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria 1 Introduction Martin Schneider Oesterreichische Nationalbank The housing sector is one of the most important sectors of an economy. Since residential

More information

AN ECONOMIC, FISCAL AND CAPITAL ASSET IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THIRTEEN PROPOSED NEW DEVELOPMENTS ON THE TOWN OF DENTON, MARYLAND.

AN ECONOMIC, FISCAL AND CAPITAL ASSET IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THIRTEEN PROPOSED NEW DEVELOPMENTS ON THE TOWN OF DENTON, MARYLAND. AN ECONOMIC, FISCAL AND CAPITAL ASSET IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THIRTEEN PROPOSED NEW DEVELOPMENTS ON THE TOWN OF DENTON, MARYLAND Prepared for The Denton Town Council Denton, Maryland by Dean D. Bellas, Ph.D.

More information

City Futures Research Centre

City Futures Research Centre Built Environment City Futures Research Centre Estimating need and costs of social and affordable housing delivery Dr Laurence Troy, Dr Ryan van den Nouwelant & Prof Bill Randolph March 2019 Estimating

More information

Structure, Funding and Regulation of the Rental Market in Germany

Structure, Funding and Regulation of the Rental Market in Germany Structure, Funding and Regulation of the Rental Market in Germany Prof. Dr. Felix Schindler Shelter Scotland Conference, Glasgow April 17, 2012 Contents Stylized Facts about the German Housing Market Structure

More information

ARLA Survey of Residential Investment Landlords

ARLA Survey of Residential Investment Landlords Prepared for The Association of Residential Letting Agents & the ARLA Group of Buy to Let Mortgage Lenders ARLA Survey of Residential Investment Landlords March 2010 Prepared by O M Carey Jones 5 Henshaw

More information

Housing Needs Survey Report. Arlesey

Housing Needs Survey Report. Arlesey Housing Needs Survey Report Arlesey August 2015 Completed by Bedfordshire Rural Communities Charity This report is the joint property of Central Bedfordshire Council and Arlesey Parish Council. For further

More information

METREX Expert Group Affordable Housing

METREX Expert Group Affordable Housing METREX Expert Group Affordable Housing METREX 125 West Regent Street GLASGOW G2 2SA Scotland UK T. +44 (0) 1292 317074 F. +44 (0) 1292 317074 secretariat@eurometrex.org http://www.eurometrex.org 1 METREX

More information

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan Makoto Shimizu mshimizu@stat.go.jp Director, Price Statistics Office Statistical Survey Department Statistics Bureau, Japan Abstract The

More information

Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the. OTAGO Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS

Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the. OTAGO Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the OTAGO Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS 2016 ABOUT PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND Property Council New Zealand is

More information

Economy. Denmark Market Report Q Weak economic growth. Annual real GDP growth

Economy. Denmark Market Report Q Weak economic growth. Annual real GDP growth Denmark Market Report Q 1 Economy Weak economic growth In 13, the economic growth in Denmark ended with a modest growth of. % after a weak fourth quarter with a decrease in the activity. So Denmark is

More information

Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs

Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs 5 November 2015 Social rent policy: choices and trade-offs Stuart Adam, Daniel Chandler, Andrew Hood and Robert Joyce Policy background and trade-offs Robert

More information

Estimating Poverty Thresholds in San Francisco: An SPM- Style Approach

Estimating Poverty Thresholds in San Francisco: An SPM- Style Approach Estimating Poverty Thresholds in San Francisco: An SPM- Style Approach Lucas Manfield, Stanford University Christopher Wimer, Stanford University Working Paper 11-3 http://inequality.com July 2011 The

More information

Housing Market Affordability in Northern Ireland

Housing Market Affordability in Northern Ireland Housing Market Affordability in Northern Ireland A report commissioned by the Northern Ireland Housing Executive and Chartered Institute of Housing from Professor Steve Wilcox, University of York The Regional

More information

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force 3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force September 26, 2018 World Bank, 1818 H St. NW, Washington, DC MC 10-100 Linking Housing Comparisons Across Countries and Regions 1 Linking Housing Comparisons Across

More information

Housing affordability in England and Wales: 2018

Housing affordability in England and Wales: 2018 Statistical bulletin Housing affordability in England and Wales: 2018 Brings together data on house prices and annual earnings to calculate affordability ratios for national and subnational geographies

More information

Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the. WELLINGTON Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS

Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the. WELLINGTON Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS Economic Significance of the Property Industry to the WELLINGTON Economy PREPARED FOR PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND BY URBAN ECONOMICS 2016 ABOUT PROPERTY COUNCIL NEW ZEALAND Property Council New Zealand

More information

Current affordability and income

Current affordability and income Current affordability and income 21.1 Introduction...1 21.2 The relationship between intermediate and private rented markets...2 21.3 Renting privately...3 Table 1: Lower quartile rent, required household

More information

Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to December 2017 All Residents Report February 2018

Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to December 2017 All Residents Report February 2018 Radian RATE Programme STAR Survey Results April 2017 to December 2017 All Residents Report February 2018 Executive summary This report summarises the results of the continuous STAR survey of Radian s residents,

More information

Trulia s Rent vs. Buy Report: Full Methodology

Trulia s Rent vs. Buy Report: Full Methodology Trulia s Rent vs. Buy Report: Full Methodology This document explains Trulia s Rent versus Buy methodology, which involves 5 steps: 1. Use estimates of median rents and for-sale prices based on an area

More information

2012 Profile of Home Buyers and Sellers New Jersey Report

2012 Profile of Home Buyers and Sellers New Jersey Report Prepared for: New Jersey Association of REALTORS Prepared by: Research Division December 2012 Table of Contents Introduction... 2 Highlights... 4 Conclusion... 7 Report Prepared by: Jessica Lautz 202-383-1155

More information

Housing Markets: Balancing Risks and Rewards

Housing Markets: Balancing Risks and Rewards Housing Markets: Balancing Risks and Rewards October 14, 2015 Hites Ahir and Prakash Loungani International Monetary Fund Presentation to the International Housing Association VIEWS EXPRESSED ARE THOSE

More information

National Rental Affordability Scheme. Economic and Taxation Impact Study

National Rental Affordability Scheme. Economic and Taxation Impact Study National Rental Affordability Scheme Economic and Taxation Impact Study December 2013 This study was commissioned by NRAS Providers Ltd, a not-for-profit organisation representing NRAS Approved Participants

More information

PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF MARYLAND

PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF MARYLAND PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF MARYLAND Report on Options for Expanding the Electric Universal Service Program to Include Assistance to Low-Income Residential Tenants of Apartments and Condominium Owners

More information

Housing Costs and Policies

Housing Costs and Policies Housing Costs and Policies Presentation to Economic Society of Australia NSW Branch 19 May 2016 Peter Abelson Applied Economics Context and Acknowledgements Applied Economics P/L was commissioned by NSW

More information

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model 13 January 2011 1 Real Estate Market What is real estate? How big is the real estate sector? How does the market for the use of

More information

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS Box EURO AREA HOUSE PRICES AND THE RENT COMPONENT OF THE HICP In the euro area, as in many other economies, expenditures on buying a house or flat are not incorporated directly into consumer price indices,

More information

SHEPHERDS BUSH HOUSING ASSOCIATION UNDEROCCUPYING AND OVERCROWDING POLICY

SHEPHERDS BUSH HOUSING ASSOCIATION UNDEROCCUPYING AND OVERCROWDING POLICY (UNCONTROLLED WHEN PRINTED) SHEPHERDS BUSH HOUSING ASSOCIATION 1. INTRODUCTION Shepherds Bush Housing Association (SBHA) intend to avoid underoccupation of our properties and to minimise and avoid overcrowding

More information

A Guide to Developing an Inclusionary Housing Program

A Guide to Developing an Inclusionary Housing Program Richard Drdla Associates affordable housing consultants inc A Guide to Developing an Inclusionary Housing Program Developed for: Acorn Institute Canada Sept 2010 Acknowledgment This guide was prepared

More information

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership Volume Author/Editor: Price V.

More information

Netherlands office market

Netherlands office market August 212 Contents 1. Take-up of offices 2. Supply of offices State of Affairs Netherlands office market 3. Office rents 4. Office investments Colophon Composition Drs. R. L. Bak Data source NVM Data

More information

Ludgvan Parish HOUSING NEED SURVEY. Report Date: 21 st January Version: 1.2 Document Status: Final Report

Ludgvan Parish HOUSING NEED SURVEY. Report Date: 21 st January Version: 1.2 Document Status: Final Report Ludgvan Parish HOUSING NEED SURVEY Report Date: 21 st January 2019 Version: 1.2 Document Status: Author: Final Report Andrew Prendergast Rural Housing Enabler Affordable Housing Team, Cornwall Council

More information

Comparative Study on Affordable Housing Policies of Six Major Chinese Cities. Xiang Cai

Comparative Study on Affordable Housing Policies of Six Major Chinese Cities. Xiang Cai Comparative Study on Affordable Housing Policies of Six Major Chinese Cities Xiang Cai 1 Affordable Housing Policies of China's Six Major Chinese Cities Abstract: Affordable housing aims at providing low

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER 15 SIMULATING RENT SUBSIDIES FOR HOUSEHOLDS IN FLANDERS. A DISTRIBUTION ANALYSIS GERLINDE VERBIST JOSEFINE VANHILLE.

DISCUSSION PAPER 15 SIMULATING RENT SUBSIDIES FOR HOUSEHOLDS IN FLANDERS. A DISTRIBUTION ANALYSIS GERLINDE VERBIST JOSEFINE VANHILLE. discussion paper DISCUSSION PAPER 15 SIMULATING RENT SUBSIDIES FOR HOUSEHOLDS IN FLANDERS. A DISTRIBUTION ANALYSIS GERLINDE VERBIST JOSEFINE VANHILLE July 2012 F L E M O S I D I S C U S S I O N P A P E

More information

A Comparative Study on the Effectiveness of Housing Allowance on Tenant Households in the UK, the Netherlands and Sweden

A Comparative Study on the Effectiveness of Housing Allowance on Tenant Households in the UK, the Netherlands and Sweden A Comparative Study on the Effectiveness of Housing Allowance on Tenant Households in the UK, the Netherlands and Sweden Min Ah Jung PhD Student, Department of Urban Studies University of Glasgow E-mail:

More information

Housing Affordability in Lexington, Kentucky

Housing Affordability in Lexington, Kentucky University of Kentucky UKnowledge CBER Research Report Center for Business and Economic Research 6-29-2009 Housing Affordability in Lexington, Kentucky Christopher Jepsen University of Kentucky, chris.jepsen@uky.edu

More information

Interim statement from the Board of Directors for the first quarter of 2015

Interim statement from the Board of Directors for the first quarter of 2015 Regulated information - under embargo until 05/05/2015, 8 a.m. Antwerp, 5 May 2015 Interim statement from the Board of Directors Acquisition of a modern logistics site of approximately 52.000 m² in a prime

More information

Exploring Shared Ownership Markets outside London and the South East

Exploring Shared Ownership Markets outside London and the South East Exploring Shared Ownership Markets outside London and the South East Executive Summary (January 2019) Shared ownership homes are found in all English regions but are geographically concentrated in London

More information

Economic Impacts of MLS Home Sales and Purchases In The province of Québec and The Greater Montréal Area

Economic Impacts of MLS Home Sales and Purchases In The province of Québec and The Greater Montréal Area Home Sales and Purchases In The province of Québec and The Greater Montréal Area Home Sales and Purchases In The Province of Québec and The Greater Montréal Area Prepared for: The Greater Montréal Real

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2015, Volume 30 Volume Author/Editor: Martin Eichenbaum and Jonathan

More information

CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS

CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS NOVEMBER 2016 STANDARD 4 Requirements STANDARD 5 INTANGIBLE ASSETS INTRODUCTION... 75 I. CENTRAL GOVERNMENT S SPECIALISED ASSETS... 75 I.1. The collection of sovereign

More information

THE LEGAL AND FINANCIAL FRAMEWORK OF AN EFFICIENT PRIVATE RENTAL SECTOR: THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE

THE LEGAL AND FINANCIAL FRAMEWORK OF AN EFFICIENT PRIVATE RENTAL SECTOR: THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE THE LEGAL AND FINANCIAL FRAMEWORK OF AN EFFICIENT PRIVATE RENTAL SECTOR: THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE Presenter: Prof.Dr.rer.pol. Stefan Kofner, MCIH Budapest, MRI Silver Jubilee 3. November 2014 MRI Silver Jubilee

More information

Report on the methodology of house price indices

Report on the methodology of house price indices Frankfurt am Main, 16 February 2015 Report on the methodology of house price indices Owing to newly available data sources for weighting from the 2011 Census of buildings and housing and the data on the

More information

WYOMING DEPARTMENT OF REVENUE CHAPTER 7 PROPERTY TAX VALUATION METHODOLOGY AND ASSESSMENT (DEPARTMENT ASSESSMENTS)

WYOMING DEPARTMENT OF REVENUE CHAPTER 7 PROPERTY TAX VALUATION METHODOLOGY AND ASSESSMENT (DEPARTMENT ASSESSMENTS) CHAPTER 7 PROPERTY TAX VALUATION METHODOLOGY AND ASSESSMENT (DEPARTMENT ASSESSMENTS) Section 1. Authority. These Rules are promulgated under the authority of W.S. 39-11-102(b). Section 2. Purpose of Rules.

More information

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/323

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/323 29.11.2008 EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/323 INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTING STANDARD 40 Investment property OBJECTIVE 1 The objective of this standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment

More information

Document under Separate Cover Refer to LPS State of Housing

Document under Separate Cover Refer to LPS State of Housing Document under Separate Cover Refer to LPS5-17 216 State of Housing Contents Housing in Halton 1 Overview The Housing Continuum Halton s Housing Model 3 216 Income & Housing Costs 216 Indicator of Housing

More information

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners Joint Center for Housing Studies Harvard University Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners Abbe Will October 2010 N10-2 2010 by Abbe Will. All rights

More information

The Impact of Market Rate Vacancy Increases Eleven-Year Report

The Impact of Market Rate Vacancy Increases Eleven-Year Report The Impact of Market Rate Vacancy Increases Eleven-Year Report January 1, 1999 - December 31, 2009 Santa Monica Rent Control Board April 2010 TABLE OF CONTENTS Summary 1 Vacancy Decontrol s Effects on

More information

How to define, achieve and measure affordability in rental housing

How to define, achieve and measure affordability in rental housing How to define, achieve and measure affordability in rental housing Housing is a fundamental right as citizens cannot enjoy other rights without it. However, a roof over people s head is not enough to promote

More information

Young-Adult Housing Demand Continues to Slide, But Young Homeowners Experience Vastly Improved Affordability

Young-Adult Housing Demand Continues to Slide, But Young Homeowners Experience Vastly Improved Affordability Young-Adult Housing Demand Continues to Slide, But Young Homeowners Experience Vastly Improved Affordability September 3, 14 The bad news is that household formation and homeownership among young adults

More information

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Mark Livingston, Nick Bailey and Christina Boididou UBDC April 2018 Introduction The private rental sector (PRS)

More information

Resilience of national housing systems in times of a credit crunch

Resilience of national housing systems in times of a credit crunch Resilience of national housing systems in times of a credit crunch Presentation at the session Global economic crisis and housing policy response Academy of Sciences of the Czech Republic Institute of

More information

Messung der Preise Schwerin, 16 June 2015 Page 1

Messung der Preise Schwerin, 16 June 2015 Page 1 New weighting schemes in the house price indices of the Deutsche Bundesbank How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? Elena Triebskorn*, Section Business Cycle, Price and

More information

Status of HUD-Insured (or Held) Multifamily Rental Housing in Final Report. Executive Summary. Contract: HC-5964 Task Order #7

Status of HUD-Insured (or Held) Multifamily Rental Housing in Final Report. Executive Summary. Contract: HC-5964 Task Order #7 Status of HUD-Insured (or Held) Multifamily Rental Housing in 1995 Final Report Executive Summary Cambridge, MA Lexington, MA Hadley, MA Bethesda, MD Washington, DC Chicago, IL Cairo, Egypt Johannesburg,

More information

GREEN PAPER : HOUSING SUBSIDY TO TENANTS OF PUBLIC HOUSING

GREEN PAPER : HOUSING SUBSIDY TO TENANTS OF PUBLIC HOUSING GREEN PAPER : HOUSING SUBSIDY TO TENANTS OF PUBLIC HOUSING Copyright: All rights reserved Information of this website, unless otherwise indicated, is protected by copyright and you may infringe it if you

More information

Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association s Annual Meetings Mobile, Alabama, February 4-7, 2007

Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association s Annual Meetings Mobile, Alabama, February 4-7, 2007 DYNAMICS OF LAND-USE CHANGE IN NORTH ALABAMA: IMPLICATIONS OF NEW RESIDENTIAL DEVELOPMENT James O. Bukenya Department of Agribusiness, Alabama A&M University P.O. Box 1042 Normal, AL 35762 Telephone: 256-372-5729

More information

The Amsterdam housing market and the role of housing associations

The Amsterdam housing market and the role of housing associations The Amsterdam housing market and the role of housing associations presentation, 19 April, 2007 for Verein für Wohnbauförderung Wien Jeroen van der Veer Amsterdamse federatie van woningcorporaties Highest

More information

X. Xx. Evaluating requirements for market and affordable housing

X. Xx. Evaluating requirements for market and affordable housing X. Xx Evaluating requirements for market and affordable housing Evaluating requirements for market and affordable housing Professor Steve Wilcox Centre for Housing Policy University of York Professor Glen

More information

NSW Affordable Housing Guidelines. August 2012

NSW Affordable Housing Guidelines. August 2012 August 2012 NSW AFFORDABLE HOUSING GUIDELINES TABLE OF CONTENTS 1.0 INTRODUCTION... 1 2.0 DEFINITION OF KEY TERMS... 1 3.0 APPLICATION OF GUIDELINES... 2 4.0 PRINCIPLES... 2 4.1 Relationships and partnerships...

More information

3 November rd QUARTER FNB SEGMENT HOUSE PRICE REVIEW. Affordability of housing

3 November rd QUARTER FNB SEGMENT HOUSE PRICE REVIEW. Affordability of housing 3 November 2011 3 rd QUARTER FNB SEGMENT HOUSE PRICE REVIEW JOHN LOOS: HOUSEHOLD AND PROPERTY SECTOR STRATEGIST 011-6490125 John.loos@fnb.co.za EWALD KELLERMAN: PROPERTY MARKET ANALYST 011-6320021 ekellerman@fnb.co.za

More information

New affordable housing production hits record low in 2014

New affordable housing production hits record low in 2014 1 Falling Further Behind: Housing Production in the Twin Cities Region December 2015 Key findings Only a small percentage of added housing units were affordable to households with low and moderate incomes.

More information

CONTENTS. List of tables 9 List of figures 11 Glossary of abbreviations 13 Preface and acknowledgements 15 1 INTRODUCTION...19

CONTENTS. List of tables 9 List of figures 11 Glossary of abbreviations 13 Preface and acknowledgements 15 1 INTRODUCTION...19 CONTENTS List of tables 9 List of figures 11 Glossary of abbreviations 13 Preface and acknowledgements 15 1 INTRODUCTION...19 1.1 Research scope and purpose...19 1.1.1 The cases...20 1.1.2 The period of

More information

Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016

Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016 Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016 YEAR XIII No. 2 March 2017 1 Luxury Residences Report 2 nd Half 2016 Introduction Introduction and methodology 2 Luxury Residences Report 2 nd Half 2016 Introduction

More information

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 1 The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham Durham Research Paper Michael Ni TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 2 Introduction Real

More information

BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 10

BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 10 BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 10 1. The client should give you a copy of their income and expense statements for the last 3 years showing their rental income by

More information

Housing Affordability in New Zealand: Evidence from Household Surveys

Housing Affordability in New Zealand: Evidence from Household Surveys Housing Affordability in New Zealand: Evidence from Household Surveys David Law and Lisa Meehan P A P E R P R E P A R E D F O R T H E N E W Z E A L A N D A S S O C I A T I O N O F E C O N O M I S T S C

More information

Auditing PP&E, Including Leases

Auditing PP&E, Including Leases Auditing PP&E, Including Leases Learning Objectives Discuss typical audit risks and special considerations. Tailor an audit plan to assessed audit risk. Explain key controls related to PP&E. Describe lease

More information