Percentage Leases and the Advantages of Regional Malls

Similar documents
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Rent economic rent contract rent Ricardian Theory of Rent:

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

Oil & Gas Lease Auctions: An Economic Perspective

Rockwall CAD. Basics of. Appraising Property. For. Property Taxation

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

Incentives for Spatially Coordinated Land Conservation: A Conditional Agglomeration Bonus

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association s Annual Meetings Mobile, Alabama, February 4-7, 2007

RESEARCH ON PROPERTY VALUES AND RAIL TRANSIT

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

Illustrations of Financing and Tax Transfers in Owner Financed Real Estate Sales

Maximization of Non-Residential Property Tax Revenue by a Local Government

Solutions to Questions

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

On the Choice of Tax Base to Reduce. Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the Context of Electricity. Generation

Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis

Accounting for Amalgamations

Land-Use Regulation in India and China

THE REAL ESTATE INDUSTRY 3 PERSPECTIVES

EITF Issue No EITF Issue No Working Group Report No. 1, p. 1

Real Estate Reference Material

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

Initial sales ratio to determine the current overall level of value. Number of sales vacant and improved, by neighborhood.

An Evaluation of Ad valorem and Unit Taxes on Casino Gaming

Cube Land integration between land use and transportation

Accounting for Amalgamations

Chapter 2 Rent and the Law of rent

Affordable Housing Policy. Economics 312 Martin Farnham

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore

Kane County. Division of Transportation. Technical Specifications Manual for Road Improvement Impact Fees Under Kane County Ordinance #07-232

On the Disutility and Discounting of Imprisonment and the Theory of Deterrence

Northgate Mall s Effect on Surrounding Property Values

will not unbalance the ratio of debt to equity.

The Impact of the New Revenue Standard on Real Estate Sales

Valuation techniques to improve rigour and transparency in commercial valuations

Impact Of Financing Terms On Nominal Land Values: Implications For Land Value Surveys

LKAS 17 Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 17

BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 9

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373

International Accounting Standard 17 Leases. Objective. Scope. Definitions IAS 17

A Historical Perspective on Illinois Farmland Sales

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

concepts and techniques

Oligopoly Theory (8) Product Differentiation and Spatial Competition

The joint leases project change is coming

Leases. (a) the lease transfers ownership of the asset to the lessee by the end of the lease term.

Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property

2015 IBC Allowable Heights and Areas

Procedures Used to Calculate Property Taxes for Agricultural Land in Mississippi

SSAP 14 STATEMENT OF STANDARD ACCOUNTING PRACTICE 14 LEASES

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force

Implications of Alternative Farm Tractor Depreciation Methods 1. Troy J. Dumler, Robert O. Burton, Jr., and Terry L. Kastens 2

Chapter 13. Why Is Housing Different? Why is Housing Different? Questions to Address. Questions to Address

James Alm, Robert D. Buschman, and David L. Sjoquist In the wake of the housing market collapse

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

CABARRUS COUNTY 2016 APPRAISAL MANUAL

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL

BUSI 398 Residential Property Guided Case Study

Chapter 37. The Appraiser's Cost Approach INTRODUCTION

Naked Exclusion with Minimum-Share Requirements

VALUATION CONSIDERATIONS AND METHODS FOR A PATENT VALUATION ANALYSIS

Natural Resources Journal

Working Paper nº 16/12

Single Payments of the CAP: Where Do the Rents Go?

METHODOLOGY GUIDE VALUING LANDS IN TRANSITION IN ONTARIO. Valuation Date: January 1, 2016

Lease modifications. Accounting for changes to lease contracts IFRS 16. September kpmg.com/ifrs

LeaseCalcs: The Great Wall

NEW APPROACHES TO THE THEORY OF RENTAL CONTRACTS IN AGRICULTURE. Clive Bell and Pinhas Zusman

2. The, and Act, also known as FIRREA, requires that states set standards for all appraisers.

Evaluation of Vertical Equity in Residential Property Assessments in the Lake Oswego and West Linn Areas

The Structure of a Retail Lease

Reg. Section 15a.453-1(c)(2) Installment method reporting for sales of real property and casual sales of personal property

Flexible Cash Leasing of Cropland

2011 ASSESSMENT RATIO REPORT

The capitalization rate is essential to any analysis through the income

Landlord Survey. Changes, trends and perspectives on the student rental market.

APPENDIX B. Fee Simple v. Conservation Easement Acquisitions NTCOG Water Quality Greenprint - Training Workshops

Application of the Residual Approach to Value

SLAS 19 (Revised 2000) Sri Lanka Accounting Standard SLAS 19 (Revised 2000) LEASES

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard-LKAS 17. Leases

Restoring the Past U.E.P.C. Building the Future

Equalization. Overview. Multiplier Basics

California Real Estate License Exam Prep: Unlocking the DRE Salesperson and Broker Exam 4th Edition

BUSI 331: Real Estate Investment Analysis and Advanced Income Appraisal

property even if the parties have no lease arrangement. This is often called an option contract.

Housing Costs and Policies

IFRS 16 Leases supplement

BUSI 499 Income Property Guided Case Study

Is there a conspicuous consumption effect in Bucharest housing market?

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights.

ON THE HAZARDS OF INFERRING HOUSING PRICE TRENDS USING MEAN/MEDIAN PRICES

GENERAL ASSESSMENT DEFINITIONS

Impact Fees in Illinois

Assessment-To-Sales Ratio Study for Division III Equalization Funding: 1999 Project Summary. State of Delaware Office of the Budget

Sorting based on amenities and income

RATE STUDY IMPACT FEES PARKS

Transcription:

JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH Percentage Leases and the Advantages of Regional Malls Peter F. Colwell* Henry J. Munneke** Abstract. The differences in the ownership structures of downtown retail districts and shopping centers may give rise to varying space allocations and rental contracts found in these markets. This article specifically examines the value-enhancing aspects of percentage leases and explores the mechanisms of tenant mix, risk sharing and rent discrimination through which this value is created. The use of percentage leases may lead to superior returns by allowing a rent structure that approaches perfect price discrimination. Risk sharing through the use of percentage leases may also create value for the property owner and lead to lower rents for tenants. Introduction In what important dimensions are shopping centers superior to downtown retail districts? It is fairly obvious that they are located differently and the shopping center location may be superior in providing access for shoppers using contemporary modes of transport. Access may relate to attributes such as proximity to circumferential highways or the adequacy or price of parking. What probably is less obvious, but arguably no less important, is that downtown retail shops have many owners (i.e., are owned atomistically), whereas shopping centers are collections of stores owned by a single entity. This ownership difference gives rise to differences in space allocation and rental contracts. Shopping centers, especially regional malls, provide a context in which it is possible to use percentage lease contracts in which rent is a percentage of the tenant s gross income. This article shows that percentage leases, in the jargon of real estate practice, create value. Three mechanisms by which percentage leases create value are diversification, risk sharing and rent discrimination. The methodology in this article is theoretical, based on a series of graphical presentations. The techniques are well established, for example using measures of expected utility and the analysis of the benefits of trade through Edgeworth boxes. These techniques have not before been applied in a systematic explanation of the value-enhancing aspects of percentage leases: tenant mix, risk sharing and rent discrimination. Recent work by Lee (1988), Vandell and Carter (1993) and Eppli and Benjamin (1994) provide extensive overviews of the general literature concerning retail research. 1 *University of Illinois, Urbana, IL 61821 or pcolwell@staff.uiuc.edu. ** University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602-6255 or hmunneke@cba.uga.edu. 239

240 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH The theory presented provides insight into the practical use of percentage leases and their possible role in urban spatial organization. The inclusion of percentage rents within a property s rent structure can lead to superior returns over a uniform rent structure and can also lead to possible benefits to the tenant via lower rents. Even though the use of percentage leases may create value, the ownership structure of downtown retail districts is not conducive to the use of percentage leases. Thus, the benefit associated with percentage leases varies spatially, affecting the spatial organization of shopping. This article is divided into five parts, the first three are devoted to diversification, risk sharing and rent discrimination, respectively. In the final two sections, we offer practical applications and our conclusions. Diversification A landlord acting in much the same way as an insurance company may add value to a portfolio of leases by bringing together tenants with different income prospects, if the incomes of the tenants are not perfectly positively correlated. The tenants are attracted by the risk reduction associated with percentage leases when compared to flat rent contracts. Consider the case of a landlord with a portfolio of two leases. Further, consider an extreme case in which the tenants have one of two gross incomes, low income or high income. Still further, assume that the incomes of these tenants are perfectly negatively correlated, when one experiences the low income the other experiences the high income. Under these conditions, the principles relating to diversification can be shown by the use of an Edgeworth box diagram (see Exhibit 1). The sides of the Edgeworth box represent a tenant s income prospects net of all costs except rent. The longer horizontal sides represent high income net of non-rent costs and the shorter vertical sides represent low income net of non-rent costs. It is assumed that non-rent costs are proportional to income, so the slope of the diagonal line connecting the opposite corners of the box is the ratio of the two gross incomes. The tenant s rents are measured from the upper right-hand corner, with the remaining portion of income net of non-rent cost referred to as net income. Net income is defined here as gross income minus the non-rent costs of operation (income net of non-rent cost) minus rent. Note that the tenant s net income could be measured from the lower left-hand corner. Flat rent contracts, equal rent in either state of income, are found along a 45 line from the upper right-hand corner of the box. This line will be referred to as the tenants flat rent line. All contracts falling along a line perpendicular to the tenants flat rent line (45 line) produce equal receipts for the landlord (recall the covariance of the two tenants incomes). Thus, these lines will be denoted as equal-expected-rent (EER) lines. For example in Exhibit 1, contract a represents a particular flat rent contract and all contracts that produce receipts for the landlord equal to those of contact a are found along EER 1. Under a percentage rent contract, rents are proportional to income and therefore, the ratio of the rents is equal to the ratio of the gross incomes. Thus, VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 241 Exhibit 1 Value Created through Tenant Diversification percentage rent contracts fall upon the diagonal connecting the upper right-hand corner with the opposite corner of the box. Contract b is the percentage rent contract that produces rent equivalent to the flat rent contract a. Contract c is a contract in which the percentage of rent for the high income exceeds the percentage for the low income. In contrast to the landlord, each tenant faces uncertain prospects, so it is not sufficient to focus on the tenant s expected net income as an indicator of welfare. Rather, it is necessary to understand that tenants expected utility is affected by lease contracts. In an Edgeworth box diagram, this is done by utilizing indifference curves that we will refer to as equal-expected-utility (EEU) curves. The slope of an EEU curve, often called the marginal rate of substitution, is the negative of the ratio of the marginal utility at high net income to the marginal utility at low net income (i.e., probabilities are not involved because the probabilities of the two incomes are equal). If a tenant faces zero risk, net income in the high and low state are equal, and the marginal utilities must also be equal. Therefore, along a 45 line out of the lower left-hand corner, the slope of the EEU curve or marginal rate of substitution is 1, the same as the landlord s equal expected rent line. Elsewhere, the tenant s EEU curve is

242 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH convex, because the tenants are risk averse. As high net income increases and low net income decreases along an EEU curve, the marginal utility increases if income is low and the marginal utility decreases if income is high. Therefore, the ratio of marginal low net income to marginal high net income increases and the slope of the EEU curve becomes steeper. To focus on the benefits of diversification as distinct from the benefits of risk sharing, the advantage to the tenant of a percentage rent contract verses a flat rent contract will be examined holding the landlord s aggregate revenue constant (i.e., the landlord will assume no additional risk by using percentage rents in place of flat rents). Thus, risk is not introduced into the landlord s portfolio. If the landlord s position is to remain unchanged, then the resulting improvement in net income for the tenant with low income must equal the resulting decline in net income when income is high. The advantage to the tenant of a percentage rent contract in contrast to a flat rent contract can be found by comparing the flat rent contract a to the percentage contract b. Both contracts fall on the same EER line, thus providing the landlord with equivalent aggregate rent. The EEU curve that passes through contract a, EEU 1, falls below contract b (i.e., a EEU curve higher than EEU 1 goes through point b), thus the tenant prefers the percentage contract b to the flat rent contract a. This unequivocally demonstrates that the tenants are better off under the percentage lease than they were under the flat lease, holding the landlord at the same level of revenue. It cannot be argued that the percentage rent contract maximizes tenant welfare while holding aggregate rent constant, only that it offers an improvement over a flat rent contract. Actually, contract c maximizes tenant welfare in this context. The EEU curve associated with contract c would have a slope of 1 at point c, therefore the EEU curve would be tangent with EER 1 at point c. Another way to look at the problem is to hold the tenants welfare constant and identify the premium they would be willing to pay in return for the reduced risk they face as a result of the percentage lease. The landlord s rent receipts will increase by the amount that the tenants expected income declines. In Exhibit 1, the percentage contract d, provides the tenant with an equivalent level of utility to that of the flat rent contract a. The premium paid to the landlord is the difference between the increase in rent under high income and the rent decline under low income. The premium associated with contract d when compared to contract a can be represented as the difference in the levels of rent associated with each contract s EER line, as shown in Exhibit 1. The percentage rent does not represent the optimal contract in the sense of maximizing aggregate rent while holding tenant utility constant. The optimal contract would be at point e, where the EER curve is tangent to the EEU 1 curve. Although the percentage rent contract is not optimal in the sense of maximizing aggregate rent while holding tenant utility constant, it does provide a premium over a flat rent contract. While percentage rent contracts have been shown to be superior to flat rent contracts, it appears that even more extreme rent contracts are superior to percentage leases. VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 243 This appearance results from artificially constraining of the landlord to a riskless position. On the other hand, this constraint is useful in distinguishing the benefits of diversification from the benefits of risk sharing. Risk Sharing 2 To focus on the value creation associated with risk sharing alone, the gains associated with diversification from altering the rent contingencies in the lease must be removed. This can be accomplished by assuming a landlord with a single tenant (i.e., atomistic ownership). As before, assume that the tenant has uncertain income in that income could be either high or low. The different levels of income are assumed to occur with equal probability. The question is whether moving away from a contract with flat rent could benefit one party (i.e., the tenant or the landlord) without injuring the other. If so, it should be a simple matter to redistribute the gains so both would be made better off by the change. Of course, a flat rent contract produces a certain outcome for the landlord while requiring the tenant to bear all of the risk. We would first like to show that holding the tenant s expected utility constant, but decreasing his risk, will cause the landlord to share risk and may cause the landlord s expected utility to increase. The proposition that risk sharing necessarily creates value actually can be proven using an Edgeworth box diagram (see Exhibit 2). When the landlord faces uncertain prospects, we must use indifference curves to judge landlord welfare. The landlord s equal-expected-utility (eeu) curves have the same direction of curvature relative to the upper right-hand corner of the box as the tenant s EEU curves do relative to the lower left-hand corner. Both the tenant and landlord are risk averse. The landlord s eeu curves have a slope of 1 at their intersection with the tenant s flat rent line. At points along the tenant s flat rent line there is certainty for the landlord (i.e., regardless of the state of income, rents are equal), thus the numerator and denominator of the marginal rate of substitution are equal. Beginning with flat rent contract a, and holding the tenant s expected utility constant leads us to percentage rent contract d. The landlord is better off with contract d than with contract a; contract d is associated with a higher level of expected utility than contract a. This demonstrates conclusively that risk sharing via percentage rents is superior to a flat rent contract. Note however that the landlord s utility would be maximized at an even more extreme contract f, the tangency point of eeu 2 and EEU 1. The landlord receives an increase in expected rent to overcome the increase in risk of moving from a certain flat rent to a contract in which rent is related to the tenant s income. In Exhibit 2, the increase in expected rent could be illustrated as the difference between the EER line which is tangent to eeu 1 at point a and the higher EER through point g. The tenant, in order to maintain a constant level of satisfaction, must enjoy an offsetting decline in the variation of net income. The decline in variation of net income can be seen as the relatively large change in rents for high income when

244 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH Exhibit 2 Value Created through Risk Sharing compared to the change in rents for low income when moving from a flat rent contract a to the percentage contract g. The decline in the difference between the high and low outcomes is exactly equal to the new variation in rent received by the landlord. Another way of looking at the problem would be to hold landlord expected utility constant. Again, starting with contract a, the percentage rent contract g makes the tenant better off but not as well off as contract h, found at the tangency point of eeu 1 and EEU 2. Once again, we see that risk sharing by the use of percentage rents is superior to a flat rent contract. The final percentage rent contract would be negotiated somewhere between contracts d and g depending on the bargaining power of the two parties. While the percentage lease may not be optimal, it approximates an optimal contract under the various conditions specified. Risk sharing always creates value if the parties to the contract are risk averse. Rent Discrimination Does a competent manager of a mall rent a vacant store to the highest bidder? This is the competitive result that should be found in downtown s with atomistic ownership, VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 245 but this is not optimal behavior for the manager of a mall. Rent discrimination, charging different rents to different retailers, is optimal. This optimal rent strategy has important implications. First, it alters the mix of stores. Second, it creates value. As before, it is not our task to indicate how this value is distributed among tenants, landlords and shoppers, only that it exists. The two types of rent discrimination considered are simple discrimination and perfect discrimination. Simple rent discrimination is a situation where each retailer within a retail classification (e.g., shoe stores) is charged a particular rent that is different than that charged other classifications (e.g., jewelry stores). In contrast, perfect rent discrimination is a situation in which each retailer is charged a different rent so as to extract all surplus. Benjamin, Boyle and Sirmans (1992) find empirical evidence indicating the use of price discrimination in shopping center leases. Suppose the landlord owns a shopping mall of size T that contains two types of stores, type A and type B. The presence of type B stores conveys external benefits on type A stores. The magnitude of these external benefits per square foot is illustrated in Exhibit 3 by the line labeled externality effects on A and are denoted X A. Note, the magnitude of the external benefit is a function of the number of square feet that type B stores occupy. The line representing this external benefit emerges from the origin on the right, a point where no type B tenants exist, to a maximum external benefit when type B tenants occupy the maximum possible amount of space. $/sf Exhibit 3 Price Discrimination and Willingness to Pay with External Effects a b type A willingness to pay with externality effects D a +X A (T-x) type A willingness to pay rent without externality effects externality effects on A D a D A X A 0 x type A square feet type B square feet T

246 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH The willingness of type A tenants to pay rent in the absence of type B tenants and any externalities, D a, is shown in Exhibit 3 by the line labeled type A willingness to pay rent without externality effects. This would be like allowing only shoe stores in the mall. The vertical summation of the external effect on A(X A ) and type A s willingness to pay rent without externality effects (D a ) identifies the willingness of type A tenants to pay rent per square foot allocated to type A(D A ). The line D A is actually a locus of points along demand curves given varying allocations of type B. For example in Exhibit 3, the willingness of type A tenants to pay rent with externality given an allocation T x of type B, is equal to the vertical sum of the willingness of type A tenants to pay rent in the absence of externality effects, (D a ) and the magnitude of the externality effect on A(X A (T x)) denoted as D a X A (T x) in Exhibit 3. Point b represents the willingness to pay in the presence of externalities given an allocation of type B equivalent to T x. As the allocation to type B changes, the level of the externality effect X A (T x) changes mapping out the points of the locus. At allocation x in Exhibit 4, type A tenants would be willing to pay R x per square foot if they all paid the same rent. The total revenue from type A would equal the area of the lightly shaded rectangle (i.e., rent R x multiplied by quantity x). Marginal revenue, the change in revenue due to a unit change in square feet, is shown as a line that is twice as steep as the willingness to pay with externality effects. Again, this assumes that all type A tenants pay the same rent per square foot. The area R x x is $/sf a c R x Exhibit 4 Price Discrimination Lease Revenue with External Effects d e f b type A willingness to pay with externality effects marginal revenue with perfect discrimination D a +X A (T-x) marginal revenue D A x type A square feet MR A MRPD A type B square feet VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 247 equal to the area under the marginal revenue curve up to allocation x (i.e., the area of adr x equals the area of bdf). If the landlord requires a contract contingency where each type A tenant is charged a different rent per square foot, thereby extracting all surplus, then the marginal revenue from imposing perfect price discrimination would be higher at each allocation. The surplus at allocation x is shown by the darkly shaded triangle ( br x c); the total revenue is the area of the shaded trapezoid. The area of the trapezoid is equal to the area under the curve labeled marginal revenue with perfect discrimination. A landlord may use percentage rent contracts to create a contingent contract that calls for a different rent from every tenant. For example, a landlord that charges type A tenants a base rent of R x per square foot with a contingency that if income rises above R x /r, the tenants must pay 100r% of their income as rent; a contingent contract that potentially calls for a different rent from every tenant. If a tenant s willingness to pay is based roughly on income, then percentage leases approximate perfect rent discrimination. Suppose that type B tenants are anchor tenants and get little or no positive externalities from type A tenants. The willingness to pay without externalities is then the same as that with externalities and the same as the marginal revenue with perfect price discrimination. Furthermore, anchor tenants are likely to have much flatter demand curves because their opportunities include many close substitutes (e.g., freestanding stores outside of the mall s ring road). Exhibit 5 illustrates an extreme case in which type B tenants have a perfectly elastic demand curve. In this case, type B tenants have marginal curves that are identical to their average curve, the flat demand curve. If retail space is leased to the highest bidder (i.e., if the landlord were playing a competitive/ downtown game), then the landlord s portfolio of leases would move toward the situation illustrated in Exhibit 5 with all rents equal at the amount that the marginal tenants are willing to pay; R 1A and R 1B for type A and B tenants, respectively. Under this scenario, a majority of space, x 1, would be allocated to type A tenants and T x 1 to type B tenants. The landlord s revenue would equal the area of the rectangle with the darkest shading (rectangle 0R 1A R 1B T). Suppose, on the other hand, that space is leased so as to maximize revenue and that it is possible to rent discriminate across tenant types. That is, it is not possible for a tenant to rent space as a shoe store and then switch merchandise to become a jewelry store. In this case of simple rent discrimination, the allocation of space would be at x 2 with a majority of the space now being allocated to type B tenants, with much less allocated to type A tenants. Rent per square foot for type A tenants would be R 2A and R 1B for type B tenants. Under simple rent discrimination, the landlord s revenue is greater than if leased to the highest bidder by the area the triangle with the lightest shading ( bjr 1A ). Finally, imagine that the landlord possesses contract attributes, perhaps percentage leases, that allow him to engage in perfect rent discrimination. Not only can different

248 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH $/sf Exhibit 5 Price Discrimination Lease Revenue without External Effects D B = MR B = MRPD B R 2A R 3A MR A D A R 1A j h MRPD A g R 1B 0 type A square feet x 2 x 3 x 1 type B square feet T base rents be set for different types of tenants, but also higher than minimum gross income yields proportionately higher rent. In the case of perfect rent discrimination illustrated in Exhibit 5, the allocation is at x 3, which falls between the two extremes already shown. It is not a general rule that the allocation with perfect rent discrimination falls between the competitive and the simple price discrimination allocations. Rather, it comes directly from the assumption that type B tenants have a flat demand curve. The rent charged type A tenants is R 3A, whereas the rent charged type B tenants is still R 1B. What really should interest us is the implication for revenue. The revenue generated under perfect rent discrimination is equal to the entire shaded area in Exhibit 5 and provides the landlord with the highest level of revenue of the cases considered. The revenue under perfect rent discrimination is greater than the revenue under simple price discrimination by the area of the triangle with the intermediate shading ( ahj). There are other implications of perfect rent discrimination. Suppose that under simple rent discrimination the landlord maximizes revenue by holding some stores vacant. It can be that the same situation would call for zero vacancies if perfect rent discrimination were possible. Suppose that a mall has two types of tenants, A and C. Type A tenants receive external benefits from type C tenants but not vice versa. Both types of tenants have downward sloping demand curves. The marginal revenue curve VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 249 for type C tenants under perfect rent discrimination is the same as their demand curve (see Exhibit 6). Let us assume that the marginal cost of occupancy is zero. This means that the landlord s expenses are the same regardless of the level of occupancy or vacancy,. It is not a problem to assume otherwise, the marginal cost of occupancy could be negative or positive where negative (positive) means that vacant space costs the landlord more (less) than occupied space. Under the assumption of marginal cost of occupancy being zero, a simple rent discriminating landlord will not allocate space so as to equate the marginal revenues if the marginal revenues are equated at a negative value. That is, it pays the landlord to back off on occupancy to the point where the marginal revenue from each tenant type is zero. In Exhibit 6, the vacancy desired by a simple rent discriminating landlord is shown as v. This is the gap between the horizontal intercepts of the marginal revenue curves. Thus, setting marginal revenue equal to zero for each type of tenant does not fully utilize the rentable space. The rents charged type A and type C tenants by the simple rent discriminating landlord are R 1A and R 1C, respectively. In contrast, the perfect rent Exhibit 6 Price Discrimination Lease Revenue and Occupancy Levels $/sf D C = MRPD C D A R 1C R 2A R 1A MR C MR A R 2C MRPD A 0 x 2 v T type A square feet type C square feet

250 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH discriminator would choose the allocation x 2 with no vacancy. This allocation is that which equates the perfect price discriminating marginal revenue for each type of tenant. Recall that for tenant type C, the demand curve and the perfect rent discriminating marginal revenue curve are one and the same. The base rents charged type A and type C tenants are R 2A and R 2C, respectively. The relative rents reverse when simple and perfect rent discrimination are compared. Type A tenants are charged more base rent than type C with perfect rent discrimination, but type A tenants are charged less rent than type C with simple rent discrimination. As a side issue, note that the relative allocations are very different in Exhibits 5 and 6. In Exhibit 5, the perfect rent discrimination produces an allocation between those of simple rent discrimination and competition. In Exhibit 6, the competitive allocation (i.e., where the demand curves cross) is between the extremes of simple and perfect rent discrimination. Implications The practical applications of the theory in this article are to alert property managers, urban economists and urban planners to the source of a new view of urban spatial organization. First, property managers should take from this article a new appreciation of the importance of charging different rents to different tenants. They can achieve superior returns by traditional price discrimination (i.e., charging higher rents to less rent sensitive tenants), but may push the envelope further by recognizing that percentage rents may move the rent structure toward perfect price discrimination. Property managers and tenants should begin to recognize the gains both sides of the lease contract may get from the risk sharing aspects of percentage leases. Tenants may share in any benefits that appear to accrue to landlords via lower rents. Tenants should be drawn to the insurance features of percentage leases. Of course, shoppers may be advantaged by lower prices emerging from the benefits of tenants. Finally, this article alerts urban economists and urban planners to an alternative view of the decline of downtown shopping associated with the rise of suburban malls. To some extent, this change in the spatial organization of shopping may be due to the fact that the downtown ownership structure does not facilitate the use of percentage leases and the benefits that accrue from these leases. In the most down-to-earth terms possible, property managers in some areas of real estate should not develop uniform rent policies, neither should they necessarily rent to the highest bidder. Planners, on the other hand, should not think that physical changes to the downtown, such as creating malls by closing streets, will be sufficient to return downtowns to their previous dominance in shopping. Rather, the property-rights/ ownership-structure may be an impediment to the return of downtown shopping as a result of limiting the nature of leases. Conclusion Three mechanisms are important in explaining the usefulness of percentage leases. These are diversification, risk sharing and rent discrimination. These mechanisms, via VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998

PERCENTAGE LEASES AND THE ADVANTAGES OF REGIONAL MALLS 251 percentage leases, provide a landlord with a portfolio of leases an opportunity for gains over flat rent contracts. Whether this opportunity exists or not depends on the diversity of the tenants income prospects. In general, it pays to share risk if the parties to a contract are each risk averse. This is as true in the context of retail leases as any other. Rent discrimination influences the allocation of space and the aggregate rent that can be generated. Atomistic downtown storeowners do not have the ability to benefit from diversification and rent discrimination, but mall owners do. Either atomistic or mall landlords may benefit from risk sharing, but the confidence a landlord has in tenants gross income figures and thus the opportunity to risk share, may be closely associated with national tenants and regional malls. While this article outlines three of the mechanisms that make percentage leases create value, it does not exhaust all of the possibilities. For example, as noted in Miceli and Sirmans (1992), percentage leases may resolve what would otherwise be an agency problem. If, for example, the levels of mall advertising, maintenance and security are influenced by manager effort and if these levels affect the incomes of the tenants, it may be desirable to involve the landlord in the businesses of the tenants via percentage leases. The presence of this incentive will induce the landlord to provide an appropriate level of effort. Note that under flat rent contracts, if the landlord s effort has no influence on the level rent collected, then he maximizes profits by setting the level of effort to zero (see Miceli and Sirmans, 1992). Of course, the use of net leases (i.e., charging tenants for operating expenses) substantially diminishes the impact of this agency problem since the landlord can pass the costs on to the tenant. A percentage lease with a base can also be thought of as a call option. While this article is concerned with the advantages of percentage leases, there are contexts in which percentage leases are inappropriate. A landlord must have confidence in the gross income figures provided by the tenant before the use of a percentage lease can be justified. Landlords may take some comfort in the fact that the tenant must report the same figures to the sales and income tax authorities so the landlord can free-ride on their monitoring programs. However, such comfort may be placing too much weight on a very thin reed (i.e., governmental monitoring). There may be some incentives not to cheat beyond the sanctions imposed by the tax authorities and landlord. These incentives may include the desire to establish an accurate sales record that can be revealed for an anticipated sale of the business, as well as ethical and religious proscriptions against lying. Nevertheless, a retail establishment may have some tendency to skim (i.e., close the cash register at some point during the day), thereby cheating both the tax authorities and the landlord who uses percentage lease contracts. If the landlord believes that some tenant attribute is associated with skimming but that the amounts skimmed are somewhat proportional to actual gross income, the landlord would tend to raise the percentage for tenants with that attribute. This is a lemons problem and would force all such tenants to skim. The opposite effect might be found for traditional money laundering stores (e.g., arcade games). These stores would tend to report more income than they produce possibly causing landlords to charge them lower percentages. There is an important exception to this propensity to lie. National tenants tend to provide honest figures

252 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE RESEARCH because they must report to the home office, as well as to the tax authorities and the landlord. Thus regional malls, that exclusively, or nearly exclusively, lease to national tenants, are the prime candidates for the use of percentage leases. Notes 1 For readers interested in studies exploring the determinants of shopping center rents, see Benjamin, Boyle and Sirmans (1990), Gatzlaff, Sirmans and Guidry (1993) and Sirmans and Diskin (1994). 2 Inspired by Brueckner (1993) and by conversations with Jan K. Brueckner. References Benjamin, J. D., G. W. Boyle and C. F. Sirmans, Retail Leasing: The Determinants of Shopping Center Rents, Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 1990, 18, 302 12., Price Discrimination in Shopping Center Leases, Journal of Urban Economics, 1992, 32, 299 17. Brueckner, J. K., Inter-Store Externalities and Space Allocation in Shopping Centers, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1993, 7, 5 16. Eppli, M. J. and J. D. Benjamin, The Evolution of Shopping Center Research: A Review and Analysis, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1994, 9, 5 32. Gatzlaff, D, H., G. S. Sirmans and B. A. Diskin, The Effect of Anchor Tenant Loss on Shopping Center Rents, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1994, 9, 99 110. Lee, K., The Economics of Shopping Centers: A Literature Survey, Working Paper, University of Illinois, 1988. Miceli, T. J. and C. F. Sirmans, Contracting With Spatial Externalities and Agency Problems: The Case of Shopping Center Leases, Working Paper, The University of Connecticut, 1992. Sirmans, C. F. and K. A. Guidry, The Determinants of Shopping Center Rents, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1993, 8, 107 16. Vandell, K. D. and C. C. Carter, Retail Store Location and Market Analysis: A Review of the Research, Journal of Real Estate Literature, 1993, 1, 13 45. VOLUME 15, NUMBER 3, 1998