presented to the Academy of Legal Studies in Business at its 77th Annual Meeting Las Vegas, Nevada July 27 - July 31, 2002 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

Similar documents
FASB Updates Business Definition

ASC 842 (Leases)

Stock Purchase Agreement Commentary

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373

Acquisition of investment properties asset purchase or business combination?

31 July 2014 Japan s Modified International Standards (JMIS): Accounting Standards Comprising IFRSs and the ASBJ Modifications

EITF Issue No EITF Issue No Working Group Report No. 1, p. 1

Business Combinations

AMERICAN SOCIETY OF APPRAISERS. Procedural Guidelines. PG-2 Valuation of Partial Ownership Interests

FASB Emerging Issues Task Force

Practice Valuations. Welcome To The Digital Learning Center. Today s Presentation. Course Faculty. Presented by. What s Your Practice Worth?

Financial Accounting Series

Business Valuation More Art Than Science

EITF ABSTRACTS. Title: Applying the Conditions in Paragraph 42 of FASB Statement No. 144 in Determining Whether to Report Discontinued Operations

Proposed FASB Staff Position No. 142-d, Amortization and Impairment of Acquired Renewable Intangible Assets (FSP 142-d)

The Financial Accounting Standards Board

Business Combinations

New Developments Summary

Reg. Section 15a.453-1(c)(2) Installment method reporting for sales of real property and casual sales of personal property

Accounting for Amalgamations

IAS Revenue. By:

MONITORDAILY SPECIAL REPORT. Lease Accounting Project Update as of May 25, 2011 Prepared by Bill Bosco, Leasing 101

IFRS Training. IAS 38 Intangible Assets. Professional Advisory Services

.01 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment for investment property and related disclosure requirements.

A TDR Program for Naples. May 11, 2007

REAL ESTATE TOPICS JUNE 1, 2008 NEGOTIATING AND STRUCTURING JOINT VENTURE AND LLC AGREEMENTS

VALUATION CONSIDERATIONS AND METHODS FOR A PATENT VALUATION ANALYSIS

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 40. Investment Property

FIRST PRINCIPLES OF VALUE

Board Meeting Handout ACCOUNTING FOR CONTINGENCIES September 6, 2007

New Accounting Rules for Nonfinancial Asset Sales

Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB)

AICPA Valuation Services VS Section Statements on Standards for Valuation Services VS Section 100 Valuation of a Business, Business Ownership

Chapter 8, Part II: Intangible Assets

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/323

Copyright 2009 The Learning House, Inc. Fixed and Intangible Assets Page 1 of 13

All Interested Parties. Rick Baumgardner, Chair Appraisal Practices Board. Date: September 9, Background

PHILIPPINE INTERPRETATIONS COMMITTEE (PIC) QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS (Q&As)

Accounting for Amalgamations

ORIGINAL PRONOUNCEMENTS

will not unbalance the ratio of debt to equity.

APES 225 Valuation Services

Re: FASB Exposure Draft, Proposed Statement of Financial Accounting Standards, "Business Combinations, a replacement of FASB Statement No.

An Overview of the Proposed Bonus Depreciation Regulations under Section 168(k)

10 Common Mistakes in Valuing ASCs and How to Avoid Them

Tax Strategies for Purchasing Going Concern Properties

roots The Substance of the Standard Contents Changes to the Accounting for Goodwill for Private Companies

11 Essential Steps to Purchasing or Selling Your Veterinary Practice

* Are the Public and Private Capital Markets Worlds Apart? M. Mark Walker, PhD, CFA, CBA

BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 10

FASB Emerging Issues Task Force. Issue No Title: Accounting by Lessees for Maintenance Deposits under Lease Arrangements

This version includes amendments resulting from IFRSs issued up to 31 December 2009.

A Primer on Customary and Reasonable Fees under TILA CRN Quarterly Meeting April 8, 2015

Acquisition of Italian On-going Business within the frame of Group to Group. Cross-Border Acquisition Projects, the. - Selected Issues -*

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

2018 Pennsylvania Housing Affordability and Rehabilitation Enhancement Fund - Final

GUIDANCE FOR LANDOWNERS AND OCCUPIERS ON CONTRIBUTIONS TOWARDS PROFESSIONAL COSTS

In December 2003 the Board issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

The cost of increasing social and affordable housing supply in New South Wales

SANTA MONICA RENT CONTROL BOARD MEMORANDUM

BUSINESS VALUATIONS: FUNDAMENTALS, TECHNIQUES AND THEORY (FT&T) CHAPTER 1

UK M&A Deals: What A US Buyer Should Expect

In December 2003 the Board issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

CITY'S BONDS TO FINANCE HOUSING PROGRAMS ARE NOT PRIVATE ACTIVITY BONDS.

In December 2003 the IASB issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

CONTACT(S) Annamaria Frosi +44 (0) Rachel Knubley +44 (0)

Financial Accounting Standards Committee

Georgia Tech Financial Analysis Lab 800 West Peachtree Street NW Atlanta, GA

BUSINESS COMBINATIONS: CLARIFYING THE DEFINITION OF A BUSINESS

Business Combinations IFRS 3

WHITE PAPER. New Lease Accounting Rules

BUSINESS VALUATIONS: FUNDAMENTALS, TECHNIQUES AND THEORY (FT&T) CHAPTER 6

Intangibles Goodwill and Other (Topic 350), Business Combinations (Topic 805), and Not-for-Profit Entities (Topic 958)

Real Estate Syndication Income 19,451 NOTE

July 17, Technical Director File Reference No Re:

The New Form 8-K: Interpretive Issues for REITs and REOCs

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

ISSUES RELATING TO COMMERCIAL LEASING. SWITZERLAND Pestalozzi

STOCK PURCHASE AGREEMENT. This Stock Purchase Agreement is entered into as of by a Delaware corporation (the Company ), and (the Purchaser ).

Understanding Costs and Benefits

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

BUYER S ACQUISITION OUTLINE

property even if the parties have no lease arrangement. This is often called an option contract.

GASBs Presented by: William Blend, CPA, CFE

December 13, delivery: To: Subject: File Reference No

Accounting Of Intangible Assets Indian as- 26

Exposure Draft (ED) 64 Summary Leases

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard-LKAS 40. Investment Property

REAL ESTATE MARKET AND YOUR TAX

Paragraph s 8, 9, and 10 from NACVA. Letter of October 27, 2016

Paragraph 5.b. We ask that the Board provide a definition of the term biological assets.

Center for Entrepreneurial Studies, Stanford Graduate School of Business. Summary of Primary Issues in Acquisition Transactions

Incentives for Spatially Coordinated Land Conservation: A Conditional Agglomeration Bonus

Accounting for Tangible Capital Assets

CONTRACTS UNDER THE UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE THE MODERN LAW OF SALES MAY BE SUMMARIZED IN ONE BRIEF STATEMENT: LET THE SELLER BEWARE!

LeaseCalcs: Expand Without Reducing Profits? Yes!

IFRS - 3. Business Combinations. By:

Joint Ownership And Its Challenges: Using Entities to Limit Liability

Presented by: Charles J. Heiny Attorney and Certified Public Accountant

ORIGINAL PRONOUNCEMENTS

Transcription:

"Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" Please do not cite, this is a preliminary scoping document. For a copy of this document visit: http://cba.unomaha.edu/faculty/mohara/web/alsb02covenant.pdf by Michael J. O'Hara, J.D., Ph.D. Finance, Banking, and Law Department College of Business Administration University of Nebraska at Omaha Omaha NE 68182 mohara@unomaha.edu voice (402) 554-2823 fax (402) 554-2680 presented to the Academy of Legal Studies in Business at its 77th Annual Meeting Las Vegas, Nevada July 27 - July 31, 2002 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" A covenant not to compete attempts to sculpt the market. As with all art, beauty is in the eye of the beholder. OUTLINE OF THE LEGAL ANALYSIS A covenant not to compete attempts to control market participants. The parties to a covenant not to compete might share a variety of commercial relationships. Some of the most frequent are employer-employee and sale of a business or significant business asset. Because an employment relationship often generates a covenant embedded in an adhesion contract, this paper will focus on commercial relationships. Regardless of the initial relationship, central to the covenant not to compete (CntC) is the belief that the identity of your competitor has a material impact on market conditions and opportunities. When an employee is significant to the success of a firm, either as a contributor or as risk, the employee should be and quite often is covered by a covenant not to compete. These ancillary contracts often are ignored once created, until the covenant is violated. Opportunities for valuation exist throughout the life cycle of the covenant. Violation presents one valuation opportunity. However, this paper will be much broader in focus. Rather than merely looking at an enforcement value, this paper will address valuation O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 1 of 6

concerns across the entire life cycle ranging from prior to the creation, through asset management, and to termination. Let's start by quickly sketching out the legal dimensions of this asset. Covenants not to compete, in the USA, are permissible, but are not favored by the law. Such covenants restrain trade, but may be allowed if supported by another public policy. A valid covenant not to compete must be ancillary to a legitimate business purpose. For example, it is quite ordinary for covenants to protect the sale of good will or to protect trade secretes disclosed in the ordinary course of employment. Each jurisdiction has its own law governing covenants not to compete, but the USA States are relatively uniform in their description of the boundaries of a valid covenant. All States allow covenants not to compete that are ancillary to or are proportional to the parties' legitimate business interests and which restrain no more than a reasonable time and a reasonable geographic area. While the States use the same words, they do not use the same meanings for those words. For example, in Nebraska a presumptively reasonable time and area is one year and one county; while in neighboring South Dakota a presumptively reasonable time and area is two years and one county. Upon proof to the court, the parties may enforce greater times and greater areas that are sufficient and necessary to protect the parties' legitimate business interests. To date, the greatest time and area allowed in Nebraska is five years and five counties for a specialist in farm and ranch taxation doing business in the center of that rural State. An additional variation is each Stat's judicial reaction to an over broad covenant. The courts have three basic approaches of to an over broad contractual term that the law does not favor: reform versus sever versus void. Assume a jurisdiction that requires covenants not to compete to be limited to no more than one year and one county. Next, assume the legitimate business interests of the parties can support such a covenant, but the parties (for whatever reason) enter a covenant protecting two years and two counties. What is the court to do? Some courts, like Colorado's, will reform the contract, limiting the enforcement of its terms to no more than the limit permissible in that context. Other courts, like Iowa's, will sever the offensive clause for the rest of the contractual relationship. As is ordinary for severing an offensive contractual provision, to be eligible for severing, the covenant needs to be [1] supported by its own consideration as well as [2] not be so central to the whole of the contractual relationship that severing the covenant would defeat the fundamental purpose of the whole contractual relationship. If either [1] or [2] are not satisfied, then the severing courts will void the entire contractual relationship as contrary to public policy, and force the parties into a court of equity. Still other courts, like Nebraska's, presume covenants not to compete serve a fundamental purpose and void the entire contractual relationship. A voiding court routinely deposits over reaching covenants and their related contracts into a court of equity. A covenant not to compete is a personal contract: who are the parties is material. Accordingly, assignment of a covenant quite likely violates the parties' reasonable O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 2 of 6

expectations. If prohibited, then a purported assignment is more likely to work as an abandonment than as an effective assignment. Of course, preventative drafting can avoid this adverse result by expressly including the right to assign. Important consequences flow from these judicial choices. The reform approach preserves the original contract and avoids enforcement beyond the bounds of the law, however it also encourages abusive over reaching by those so inclined. Conversely, a voiding court, by reducing the certainty of contract enforcement, discourages all covenants not to compete, not merely those that are over reaching. OUTLINE OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Prior to June 30, 2001, it was far easier to treat covenants not to compete merely as human resource concerns or as legal concerns. 1. However, FASB 142, Goodwill and Other Intangible Assets, took effect on that date and it requires express valuation of covenants not to compete. FASB 142 addresses financial accounting and reporting for acquired goodwill and other intangible assets. 2 FASB 142 addresses how intangible assets that are acquired individually or with a group of other assets should be accounted for in financial statements upon their acquisition. 3 FASB 142 also addresses how goodwill and other intangible assets should be accounted for after they have been initially recognized in the financial statements. 4 Previous valuation literature addressing covenants not to compete was focused in the realm of tax law. Now, valuation of covenants not to compete will be part of the balance sheet and a more explicitly managed asset. The lack of an arm's length transaction was a major source of accountancy's reticence with valuing a covenant not to compete. While accountants often provide estimates of value, they usually can provide substantiation via comparable market transactions. This source of validation is not available for many forms of intangible assets. Notwithstanding that preferred validation mechanism, intangible assets have become so significant for many firms that accountancy could not avoid valuing such material assets. The three most common validation methods are the market method, the income method, and the cost method. As noted, there is a paucity of comparable market transactions. While cost frequently can be known via historical arm's length transactions, with respect to intangible assets historical costs may bear no relationship with present 1 FASB 142 has three potential effective dates: fiscal years starting after March 15 may make an early adoption; June 30 applies to all new acquisitions of assets, and all fiscal years starting after December 15, 2001 are subject to FASB 142. 2 FASB 142 supersedes APB Opinion No. 17, Intangible Assets. 3 If an intangible asset is acquired in a business combination, then see FASB 141. 4 See also, FASB Concepts Statement No. 2, Qualitative Characteristics of Accounting Information, FASB Concepts Statement No. 7, Using Cash Flow Information and Present Value in Accounting Measurements, FASB Statement No. 2, Accounting for Research and Development Costs, and FASB Interpretation No. 4, Applicability of FASB Statement No. 2 to Business Combinations Accounted for by the Purchase Method. O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 3 of 6

value. Accordingly, the preferred valuation method for intangible assets under FASB 142 is the discounted present value of future net income streams. Of course, those future costs and future incomes must be estimated. Such DPV net income estimates can yield speculative values depending upon the relative certainties attached to the critical components of that estimation. Valuing a covenant not to compete requires valuation of the known and the unknown. Much has been written on the role of asymmetric information in valuation (i.e., value estimation is more tightly dispersed with information than without). Unknown components of a covenant's value estimation can be, but need not be, reflective of asymmetric information. Often, neither party will know and neither party will be able to know. Many times it will not be a situation of asymmetric information: there will be an information void. Since fear springs from the unknown, it is important to bear in mind that fear is likely to generate an elevated value. A covenant not to compete covers a reasonable time and a reasonable geographic area. While the law will require objective specificity of the reasonable time and area (e.g., one calendar year and one county), both of those markers, in practice, are inherently imprecise. While the county line may not move, the market lines are prone to move. Also, recall that a covenant that is drafted broadly (e.g., five years and five counties) runs a very real risk of covering far less. Dynamic definitions of the covenant's time and area are the hallmarks of expert draftsmanship. A covenant with static provisions is likely to be crafted for application at a some specific, future date. Those static terms may be reasonable neither prior to nor after than specific, future date. All too often, the parties will default to a mean estimate of the appropriate time and area. For example, many a covenant is drafted assuming application will occur after a product has been fully introduced in the market. However, application of the covenant may occur in a market with aborted product introduction or in a dying market where the product is in substantial retreat as it nears the end of its life cycle. If the parties use static and expansive terms in a dynamic market, then that market dynamism may render abusive and unreasonable the expansive terms in either an aborted market or in a dying market. Both dynamic scopes and static scopes in a dynamic market increase greatly the difficulty of accurate estimation of value. Let us now assume the parties both envision the same factual future. Their values still may diverge. The parties to a covenant not to compete may have different risk preferences (e.g., risk neutral versus risk averse) and/or different time value of a dollar preferences (i.e., discount rates). For example, because of existing cash flow requirements, one party may be risk averse towards short-term losses and risk neutral towards long-term losses. Alternatively, one party may have easy access to ample capital at prime while the other party can obtain neither the requisite magnitude of financing nor a tolerable interest rate. 5 These differences in constraints may generate different valuations 6 even when the parties predict the same factual future. 5 Commercial relationships, unlike employment relationships, are likely to present parties of substantially equal commercial sophistication with respect to the time value of money. However, it still is O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 4 of 6

A shared perception of the future will enhance the self-enforcement mechanism of a covenant. This is especially true if the parties specifically address and compensate individual risks. Some covenants bundle all risks and bundle all compensation within one simple term. Increase legal enforceability from making the contours of the parties agreement clear to the court are not the only benefits of specificity. The parties also will better perceive the covenant's incentives and rewards. Every covenant not to compete has a value not of -one- thing, but has the value of many things added together. If the covenant covers more than a minute and more than a square inch, then many "markets" are aggregated to find the value of the covenant. This too prods the parties towards accepting an average time and area along with an average value. However, the mean rarely accurately describes any one individual, much less two unique parties. The parties must be attentive to their unique context and value. For example, the strategic effect of a covenant not to compete on a party depends upon the party in question. A small local selling firm may forego far more than the large national buying firm gains; whereas a large local buying firm may gain far more than the small local selling firm foregoes. Every covenant not to compete seeks to sculpt the market. Accordingly, both the existing firms and the reasonably expected market participants should be well understood by both parties. The market consequences of a direct competitor in the market are quite different than the consequences of a strategic ally or a value chain partner. Clearly, added value springs from less competition pressure on prices. Accordingly, one undesirable consequence may be attention from antitrust enforcement officials. 7 While business acumen that prompts a competitor to secure access to competitive resources is laudable and privileged; less laudable is a competitor whose expenditures merely remove competitive resources from the market. That said, value may spring from increasing your competitor's cost of inputs. The DPV of the net income stream may increase because a covenant causes either revenue to increase and/or causes relative costs decrease. The firm should have an active process for identifying the contours of the market and for vetting its covenants not to compete. That active process should recognize that markets are dynamic. Two particularly noteworthy sources of dynamism are cost structure and diffusion rate. The cost structure of the firm and the cost structure of competitors generate significant impacts on market behavior and opportunities. Two important conditions possible for there to be material differences in sophistication that, alone, generate different perceptions of value. This could happen as a classic informational asymmetry: one party can and does perceive the contours of risk (e.g., complex and contingent payment structures) and the other does not. 6 In a commercial transaction are parties are likely to negotiate the time and area. In the parlance of negotiation the parties can "create value" by trading their differences. However, those same differences can place a cloud the "genuine" value of the covenant since neither party places a value on the covenant equal to the agreed upon value. A split-the-difference negotiation tactic may yield a signed document but may not yield an enforceable covenant. 7 Recall that the Clayton Act section 7 takes an expansive view of transactions that are "mergers". O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 5 of 6

issue from the cost structure: shut down and destructive competition. Broadly, total costs can be divided into fixed costs and variable costs. All firms seek to profit maximize. Not all firms can earn a profit, and a firm suffering losses seeks to minimize those losses. However, loss minimization may require staying open. Since fixed costs must be paid regardless of the level of output, shutting down does not reduce fixed costs. Thus, the minimum loss is equal to fixed costs. Shut down only minimizes losses when total revenue is less than variable cost. Accordingly, if a firm has high relative fixed costs (e.g., farming; airlines), rarely can the firm reduce losses by shutting down. Additionally, if this forced operation with losses is persistent (especially if many firms in the industry are similarly situated), then the firm enters destructive competition. Under destructive competition, there is a strong downward pressure on prices and total revenue, with total revenue driven down to variable costs. How does the cost structure relate to covenants not to compete? Often, the payments required by a covenant are fixed. Increasing a firm's fixed costs, especially relative to its competitors, increases the risk of destructive competition and non-recovery of those fixed costs. Paradoxically, all of the variable cost payments on the covenant still will be made. If, however, the covenant is structured so that all of the payments are variable costs for the buyer, then the covenant increases the likelihood that the buyer will shut down. Obviously, the parties have something to negotiate. In addition to cost structure, the diffusion rate can be a significant source of market dynamism. The purchaser of the covenant not to compete buys a resource. That resource is purchased either for the buyer's own use or to remove the resource from the market's stock of inputs. The particular competitive advantage that the purchase provides the buyer will dissipate as other resources diffuse into the market. Some diffusion rates can be very rapid, others may follow a normal curve. The diffusion rate of tangibles can be faster than intangibles, especially if the tangibles are fungible. However, intangibles that have unique characteristics, such as a network of acquaintances or an experience base in a market, often need to be replaced in near real time. 8 CONCLUDING COMMENTS The freedom of contract and the freedom of allocating ownership both encourage covenants not to compete that are supported by sufficient legitimate business interests of the parties. A generic value should earn less respect from the courts than a valuation that reflects the contours of the market that the parties confronted and should have reasonably expected at the time of entering the covenant. The value of such covenants will be difficult to assets. However, the significance of those assets warrants making the estimates because the firm's failure to explicitly estimate that value merely means that the person is the best position to make the estimate will be silent. FASB 142 reflects this truth. 8 If replacement can not be rushed, then the cost approach to valuation is an appropriate method of valuation. O'Hara 2002 "Valuation of a Covenant Not to Compete" ALSB 2002 Page 6 of 6