What Is Proper Tax Policy for Smokeless Tobacco Products?

Similar documents
What is Proper Tax Policy for Smokeless Tobacco Products?

Business Creation Index

State Housing Trust Fund Revenues 2017

NCSL TABLE REAL ESTATE TRANSFER TAXES

Alabama. Alaska. Arizona. Arkansas. California. Colorado

Your Guide to Real Estate Customs by State

ALI-ABA Course of Study Commercial Lending and Banking Law January 29-31, 2009 Scottsdale, Arizona

Your Guide to. Real Estate. Customs by State

Medicaid Prescription Reimbursement Information by State Quarter Ending June 2010

CBRE INDUSTRIAL & LOGISTICS SPECIAL PROPERTIES GROUP

MULTIFAMILY TAX SUBSIDY PROJECT INCOME LIMITS

Administration > Exemption Certificate Validity Periods

State Tax Credits for Historic Preservation A State-by-State Summary. States with income tax incentives States that do not tax income

SPECIAL PROPERTIES GROUP INDUSTRIAL SERVICES

REQUIRED WITNESSES FOR A MORTGAGE OR DEED OF TRUST

No Survey Required w/ Survey. Affidavit. Affidavit. Affidavit

The Subject Section. Chapter 2. Property Address

Nevada Single Document Rule

Paper for presentation at the 2005 AAEA annual meeting Providence, RI July 24-27, 2005

TO: Rural Development State Directors

AGRICULTURAL CONSERVATION EASEMENT PROGRAM AGRICULTURAL LAND EASEMENTS

Status of State PACE Programs

I. The Affordability Problem in Boston II. What is Affordable? III.Housing Costs IV.Housing Production V. What Can Public Policy Do? I.

APPLICATION FOR LEASE OF APARTMENT EQUAL HOUSING OPPORTUNITY

Goomzee Corporation Fall MLS Platforms. America s MLS Platform Vendors & Market Distribution. Goomzee Research

Marijuana and Real Estate: A Budding Issue

U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development Office of Fair Housing and Equal Opportunity. Fair Housing. It s Your Right

STATUS OF STATE PACE PROGRAMS

U.S. Home Price Insights Report

Understanding Whom the LIHTC Program Serves

REPORT TO COUNCIL City of Sacramento

Citizen s Activity Sheet

Automatic Renewal Laws in All 50 States Index

National Foreclosure Report

Tulsa County Public Service Net Values

Foreclosures Copyright 2014 Rogue Investor

VERMONT S RENTAL HOUSING AFFORDABILITY GAP CONTINUES TO GROW The Average Vermont Renter Can t Afford a Modest 2-Bedroom Apartment

Sources Consulted. International Association of Assessing Officers Standard on Ratio Studies (draft version). February.

Federal Rental Assistance Provides Affordable Homes for Vulnerable People in All Types of Communities

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

The Voice of the 1031 Industry

National Foreclosure Report

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Good design makes a difference

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

State Guide To Tax Lien And Tax Deed Investing

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

CYBER ESTATE PLANNING AND ADMINISTRATION

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

ABOUT THE UNITED TRUSTEE ASSOCIATION

District Facilities and Public Charter Schools

Collateral Risk Network Review Panel Discussion

The following is a review of the law of land trusts in all fifty states:

MedicaidEligibility Planning

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Financial Leasing of Capital Assets in Pork Production

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Testimony on OH HB 323, Foreclosure Reform, November, 2009

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development

More details >>> HERE <<<

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Horry County Personal Property Return 2017

More details >>> HERE <<<

MASON DIXON RED ANGUS ASSOCIATION

Vertical File Finding Aid 1. Vertical File. Art and Architecture Collection. New York Public Library

Short Sale Guide. The real estate agent faxes the complete Short Sale Package to , Attn: Setup.

issues key STATE ADVOCACY

AN APPRAISAL OF THE MODEL BUSINESS CORPORATION ACT S APPRAISAL RIGHTS PROVISIONS

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

APPLICATION FOR LEASE OF APARTMENT EQUAL HOUSING OPPORTUNITY

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

The Governance of Land Use

Wilcomb E. Washburn Papers,

Solar Rights in the United States

THE REVISED UNIFORM RESIDENT LANDLORD TENANT ACT (RURLTA)

Chapter 3 Real and Personal Property. Louisiana Mid-Continent Oil and Gas Association and Louisiana Oil and Gas Association

FTC S BUSINESS OPPORTUNITY RULE REDUCED DISCLOSURE BUT INCREASED COVERAGE

City Housing Trust Fund Revenues 2018

State Farmland Preferential Assessment: A Comparative Study

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

UNCLAIMED PROPERTY & ESCHEATMENT

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Management and Sale of Foreclosed Properties

US GOVERNMENT SALES GUIDE

Chapter 13. Oil and Gas Law Update

PLANNING FOR BIODIVERSITY Authorities in State Land Use Laws

Can Government Open More Doors for Borrowers?

25 Annual Water Law Conference Coronado, CA February 22-23, Fundamentals of Prior Appropriation Systems

Case No CATRICE JOHNSON; FELICIA BADON; MONA BLUNTE; TIFFANI BRUMFIELD; BERTHA WILLIAMS; ET AL

IN THE CIRCUIT COURT OF THE SEVENTEENTH JUDICIAL CIRCUIT, IN AND FOR BROWARD COUNTY, FLORIDA

Black Knight Home Price Index Report: December Transactions U.S. Home Prices Down 0.1 Percent for the Month; Up 4.5 Percent Year-Over-Year

AFFORDABLE HOUSING PRESERVATION: BUILDING A NATIONAL DATA INFRASTRUCTURE

Gardner Business Review May 2018 Applied economic analysis by the David Eccles School of Business

Transcription:

What Is Proper Tax Policy for Smokeless Tobacco Products? Fiscal Fact No. 120 by Gerald Prante March 26, 2008 (This paper is an updated version of Tax Foundation Fiscal Fact No. 65, available at http://www.taxfoundation.org/publications/show/23045.html) While there exist a large literature and extensive policy discussion on the issue of cigarette taxation, smokeless tobacco has received comparatively little attention. In the past few years, however, controversy in many state legislatures has erupted over the proper way of taxing smokeless tobacco, if it should be taxed at all. The goal of this Fiscal Fact is to clarify the rationale for excise taxation in general from a neutral public finance perspective, and specifically to explain the proper method of taxation of smokeless tobacco products and how it compares to cigarette taxation. The Fallacies of Current Tax Policy on Smokeless Tobacco Products Even though the federal government taxes smokeless tobacco at a per unit rate based upon weight, most states tax it based upon the sale price. This can be seen in the following table of the tax rates on smokeless tobacco across the country.

Table 1 Smokeless Tobacco Tax Policy Is Highly Inconsistent Across States State Tax Rate on Moist Snuff Tobacco Type of Tax (MST) Alabama 2 cents per typical can 1 Per Unit Alaska 75% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Arizona 12.3 cents per ounce Per Unit Arkansas 32% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem California 46.76 percent of wholesale price 2 Ad Valorem Colorado 40% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem Connecticut 40 cents per ounce 3 Per Unit Delaware 54 cents per ounce Per Unit Florida 25% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Georgia 10% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Hawaii 40% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Idaho 40% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Illinois 18% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Indiana 24% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Iowa $1.19 per ounce Per Unit Kansas 10% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Kentucky 9.5 cents per unit 4 Per Unit Louisiana 20% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem Maine 78% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Maryland 15% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Massachusetts 90% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Michigan 32% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Minnesota 70% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Mississippi 15% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem Missouri 10% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem Montana 85 cents per ounce Per Unit Nebraska 20% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Nevada 30% of wholesale price Ad Valorem New Hampshire 19% of wholesale price Ad Valorem New Jersey 75 cents per ounce Per Unit New Mexico 25% of product value Ad Valorem New York 37% of wholesale price Ad Valorem North Carolina 10% of wholesale price Ad Valorem North Dakota 60 cents per ounce Per Unit Ohio 17% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Oklahoma 60% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Oregon 65% of wholesale price Ad Valorem

Pennsylvania No tax N/A Rhode Island $1.00 per ounce Per Unit South Carolina 5% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem South Dakota 35% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Tennessee 6.6% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Texas 40% of manufacturer's price Ad Valorem Utah 75 cents per ounce Per Unit Vermont $1.49 per ounce Per Unit Virginia 10% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Washington 75% of wholesale price Ad Valorem West Virginia 7% of wholesale price Ad Valorem Wisconsin $1.31 per Ounce Per Unit Wyoming 20% of wholesale price (or 10% of retail) Ad Valorem 1 Alabama charges 1.5 cents per ounce of chew tobacco, and a varying rate on snuff tobacco per can, depending upon the size. 2 Adjusted annually by the California Board of Equalization 3 Connecticut charges a tax of 20 percent on other tobacco products besides snuff. 4 Kentucky charges a tax of 7.5 percent on other tobacco products besides snuff. Source: Federation of Tax Administrators; various updates compiled by Tax Foundation As Table 1 shows, the lowest tax burdens on smokeless tobacco are found in the tobaccoproducing South, which also imposes the lowest tax rates on cigarettes, although tobacco taxes on whole have grown rapidly over the past decade. But why do some states tax smokeless tobacco so heavily and some so lightly? What is the rationale for some states (like Iowa, Wisconsin, and Arizona) recently switching from an ad valorem basis to a per unit (i.e. weight-based) basis? To answer these questions and determine which states, if any, are practicing proper tax policy, we must develop a framework for explaining proper tax policy with regard to smokeless tobacco. Tobacco taxation policy should follow the framework of three crucial questions: (1) Should products like smokeless tobacco have a special tax imposed? (2) By what method should they be taxed, i.e. based on the sale price (ad valorem) or per unit? (3) What is the proper level of taxation? Should Tobacco Products Have a Special Tax? Assuming that the role of government is to prevent individuals from harming one another, and not to prevent individuals from harming themselves, then special taxes on tobacco products should exist only if those products impose significant costs on third parties. A

frequently cited example is the health care costs to other taxpayers associated with tobacco consumption. 1 Another often-cited external cost of tobacco products, cigarettes in particular, is second-hand smoke-both in public places and in homes where children reside. Smokeless tobacco, however, imposes no such harm. Other costs unfairly imposed on society from tobacco consumption have been cited, such as the unattractiveness of witnessing certain behavior associated with chew tobacco, and the message children receive as a result of viewing adult tobacco consumption. To the extent that tobacco imposes undue costs on society, specific taxation of the product may be warranted. But a government official who merely desires to influence individual consumption decisions because of his own anti-tobacco sentiment cannot be justified by an appeal to principles of sound tax policy unless one wants to go down the road of paternalistic tax policy whereby activities deemed unhealthy (like fatty foods, soft drinks, alcohol, tobacco, etc.) are subject to heavy taxation. By What Method Should Tobacco Products Be Taxed? There are two methods of levying an excise tax on any product. The first and most common type of excise tax is a per-unit tax. In this case, the tax is independent of the price of the product. The other type of excise tax is an ad valorem tax, which is akin to a typical general sales tax where the tax is a percentage of the sale price. Regardless of the rationale for the government's attempt to limit tobacco consumption via taxation-whether it is through the proper framework of controlling for negative costs imposed on others or through the authoritarian/paternalistic method of trying to control individual decisions-tobacco products should be taxed via a per-unit tax. The harm caused by a unit of tobacco is essentially unrelated to its price. A $5 pack of cigarettes would not impose any cost to society or harm any individual more than a $2 pack of cigarettes would. With respect to cigarettes, most tax-levying officials have properly understood this because every state imposes the tax based on the number of cigarettes, not based upon the sale price. However, with respect to smokeless tobacco, most states have gone in the opposite direction of sound tax policy, and have imposed ad valorem taxes, which are based upon the sale price of the smokeless tobacco. Only nine states impose the tax on a per-unit basis even though the federal government taxes moist smokeless tobacco based on weight, which is essentially a tax on quantity, and is the proper way of taxing the product. It is not logical to base the tax on the value of the product. A $6 can of premium smokeless tobacco does no greater harm to the user or to society than a $2 brand of generic smokeless tobacco, but under the current system in most states, the premium brand is charged a tax three times that of the generic brand. Much of the effect of this ad valorem tax is merely to encourage more consumption of the inexpensive brand, thereby making irrelevant much of the government policy designed to limit the quantity of tobacco consumed. What is the Proper Level of Taxation? Now that we have defined the conditions under which a government is justified in

imposing a special tax on tobacco and explained how that tax should be levied, the obvious question is what the level of taxation should be. In standard economic theory, a tax designed to compensate for a negative externality imposed on society should be levied on a per unit basis and should equal the difference between the social cost of the good (the cost to society at large) and the private cost (the cost to individual consumers). Therefore, if the social cost of tobacco consumption is greater than the total private cost, then the tax should be set at a level that will make the two costs equal, thereby improving overall societal wellbeing. The problem that governments face is calculating the social cost of tobacco and comparing it to the private cost. Often, those with certain agendas try to overstate the difference between the private cost and the social cost of tobacco in order to impose their principles of morality on everyone else. What constitutes a true cost to society is therefore always a subject of disagreement and should be carefully calculated. Policymakers should be clear about the factors involved in their calculations when they recommend a level of taxation. At the very least, the relative taxes imposed on tobacco products should be in accordance with their negative costs imposed on society. Specifically, if one pack of cigarettes imposes the same external costs on society as does one can of chew, then their respective tax amounts should be the same. Again, this is irrespective of the price of the product. Tobacco Products as a Revenue Source Recently, many policymakers have begun to look towards tobacco products merely as a source of tax revenue. Such policies are unfortunately inconsistent with sound tax policy. Arbitrarily choosing one product to raise revenue from without any account of the negative social costs the product imposes would be seen by many as a violation of individual liberty and would more appropriately be under the heading "regulatory policy." Many advocates of this type of revenue source tapping will use the excuse that "people shouldn't consume tobacco products in the first place." But under such logic, one would ban tobacco products, not impose heavy taxes upon them. Such an inconsistency exposes the true motive behind the politicians' heavily taxing tobacco products: they want to raise revenue by imposing a tax on a minority of the citizens. Summary Even if the goal of policymakers is to reduce tobacco consumption, in a free society this should be done solely for the purposes of correcting for social costs unfairly imposed on others, not to impose some individuals' moral agenda on everyone else. Taxes should not be used to impose morality; social engineering through the tax code is never sound tax policy. Because the proper purpose of tobacco taxes is to correct for market imperfections, taxes should be levied only up to the point at which the tax per unit equals the difference between the social cost of a unit of tobacco and the private cost of a unit of tobacco. This can only be accomplished with per-unit excise taxes because the dollar value of the tobacco consumed is irrelevant with respect to reducing overall consumption of tobacco. Notes 1 Some economists will note that any health care cost imposed on society is technically a transfer that has been created by government through a quasi-socialized health care system. Moreover, while it is commonly assumed that individuals' unhealthful habits must

necessarily impose health care costs on society, this is not at all the case. A field of economics known as social cost accounting attempts to discern the aggregate fiscal effects of different types of behavior, and its findings are often counterintuitive. Smoking, for example, has been found to not impose health care costs on nonsmokers. To the contrary, current federal, state, and local fiscal regimes have been found to transfer tens of billions of dollars from smokers to nonsmokers. See, for example, Patrick Fleenor, "Who Bears the Ancillary Cost of Tobacco Use?," Tax Foundation Background Paper, No. 36 (January 2001). 2008 Tax Foundation Tax Foundation 2001 L Street NW, Suite 1050 Washington, DC 20036 Ph: (202) 464-6200 Fax: (202) 464-6201 www.taxfoundation.org