Chapter 3 LANDOWNER REWARDS AND RISKS: FINANCIAL, CONSERVATION, FAMILY CONSIDERATIONS

Similar documents
Chapter 2 INTRODUCING THE PROGRAMS

General Development Plan Background Report on Agricultural Land Preservation

Farmland and Open Space Preservation Purchase of Development Rights Program Frequently Asked Questions

FARMLAND AMENITY PROTECTION. A Brief Guide To Conservation Easements

CONSERVING AGRICULTURAL LAND THROUGH COMPENSATION: A GUIDE FOR CALIFORNIA LANDOWNERS

MITIGATION POLICY FOR DISTRICT-PROTECTED LANDS

NFU Consultation Response

Special Consideration Multiple jurisdictions is cumbersome

About Conservation Easements

Using Easements to Conserve Biodiversity. Jeff Lerner Defenders of Wildlife

Appendix J Agricultural Land Preservation in Other States

Housing Authority Models FIRST NATION MODELS: COMPARITIVE REPORT

Claudia Stuart, Williamson Act Program Manager and Nick Hernandez, Planning Intern

Yolo Habitat Conservancy County of Yolo City of Davis City of Winters City of West Sacramento City of Woodland University of California, Davis

Nova Scotia Community Lands Trust Discussion Paper. Approaches to Enable Community Participation In the Purchase of Land

Transfer of Development Rights (TDR) in Practice

The Farmland Preservation Program in Sussex County

Land Trust of Santa Cruz County. Strategic Plan. July 2012 to June This is a public version of a more detailed internal plan.

Chapter 10 Local Protection Measures

Open Space. Introduction. Vision. Defining Open Space. Midway City 2017 General Plan

RESEARCH BRIEF. Jul. 20, 2012 Volume 1, Issue 12

Instructions: Script:

Rule 80. Preservation of Primary Agricultural Soils Revised and approved by the Land Use Panel during its public meeting on January 31, 2006.

GATESVILLE BEWARE!! More Observations & Warnings by Our Land Our Lives About Conservation Easements/Purchase of Development Rights

CHAIRMAN WOLPERT AND MEMBERS OF THE HOUSE LOCAL AND MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT AND URBAN REVITALIZATION COMMITTEE

Landowners, while pleased with agricultural easements, suggest improvements

Introduction to Conservation Easements. Blair Calvert Fitzsimons Chief Executive Officer

CONSERVATION EASEMENTS FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Introduction to INRMP Implementation Options

Subtitle H Agricultural Conservation Easement Program

An Accounting Tradeoff Between WRP and Government Payments. Authors Gregory Ibendahl Mississippi State University

Conservation Easements: Creating a Conservation Legacy for Private Property

CHAPTER 156: FARMLAND PRESERVATION. General Provisions. Qualifications and Certification of Farmland. Voluntary Agricultural Districts

Kent Land Trust Strategic Reassessment Project Final Report

Remains eligible for state or federal farm programs. Can use land as collateral for loans. Can reserve home lots for children

CITY OF FORT COLLINS NATURAL AREAS AND CONSERVED LANDS EASEMENT POLICY

TRANSFER OF DEVELOPMENT RIGHTS

Innovative Local Government Land Conservation Techniques

Agricultural Lease Bid Process and Policy Updated September 21, 2017

Ron Shultz, Director of Policy Washington State Conservation Commission

Summary of Key Issues from Skagit County TDR Focus Group Meetings January 7, 2014

Local Agriculture Perspectives in the Middle Rio Grande Valley

Exploring Ecosystem Services on State Trust Lands in the West

Chapter VIII. Conservation Easements: Valuing Property Subject to a Qualified Conservation Contribution

Conservation Partnering Opportunities for Military Departments, Public Agencies, and Private Conservators

CONSERVATION EASEMENTS. Public Policy Considerations for PRIVATE Land Management Harriet M. Hageman Hageman & Brighton, P.C.

2016 Highlands Region Land Preservation Status Report

Industry Focus: Agriculture ~ James L. Turner

Scorecard on the Founding Recommendations of the Ohio Farmland Preservation Task Force

A Place for Everyone:

Rents for Social Housing from

CONSERVATION EASEMENTS FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

2018 Highlands Region Land Preservation Status Report

Chapter 52 FARMLAND AND OPEN SPACE PRESERVATION

RESEARCH BRIEF. Oct. 31, 2012 Volume 2, Issue 3

Thurston County Planning Department BOARD OF COUNTY COMMISSIONERS PUBLIC HEARING DRAFT AMENDMENTS TO THE CRITICAL AREAS REGULATIONS. Chapter 24.

Dakota County Farmland and Natural Areas Program. Lake Pepin TMDL May 31, 2007

PROJECT SCORING GUIDANCE. Introduction: National Proiect Selection:

Midway City Council 16 October 2018 Work Meeting. Ordinance / General Plan Amendment

Marin County Agricultural Land Conservation Program March 1, 2014

AGRICULTURAL CONSERVATION EASEMENT PROGRAM AGRICULTURAL LAND EASEMENTS

RECITALS. B. WHEREAS, Ranch, its successors and assigns, are referred to in the Easement as the Grantor ; and

Grazing Lease Clinic: Creating Agreements for Successful Ranch Operations

Frequently Asked Questions on Sustainable & Long-Term Leases in Minnesota

No Land, No Water: Solutions and Programs for Mitigating Land Loss

protect your place Guide to Understanding Conservation Easements

Protecting Farmland in Maryland: A Review of the Agricultural Land Preservation Program

Our Proposal. The Proposal

Land Use. Land Use Categories. Chart 5.1. Nepeuskun Existing Land Use Inventory. Overview

A STUDY OF TRANSFER OF DEVELOPMENT RIGHTS (TDR) IN THURSTON COUNTY, WASHINGTON

Procedures Used to Calculate Property Taxes for Agricultural Land in Mississippi

Midway City Council 4 December 2018 Regular Meeting. Ordinance / General Plan Amendment

Conservation Easement Stewardship

To achieve growth, property development, redevelopment and an improved tax base in the cities and boroughs in the Lehigh Valley.

RECITALS. WHEREAS, the GMA requires counties to adopt county-wide planning policies in cooperation with cities within the County; and

California Office 2001 N Street Suite 110 Sacramento, CA VIA

LEGISLATIVE PURPOSES. 2. Provide sources of agricultural products within the state for the citizens of the state

Bandera Corridor Conservation Bank: a conservation story

Disappearing Idaho Farmland:

Briefing paper A neighbourhood guide to viability

CHAPTER 352 COUNTY LAND PRESERVATION AND USE COMMISSIONS

ALC Bylaw Reviews. A Guide for Local Governments

Chapter 26. Open-Space and Conservation Easements, Land Use Valuation, and Other Laws Related to the Use of Land

City and County of San Francisco

NRCS Conservation Programs

Wetland Mitigation Bank Settlement Agreement Fact Sheet

UNIFORM RULE 5. Administration of Williamson Act Contracts

PRIVATE PROPERTY PUBLIC PURPOSE

Conservation Easement Best Management Practices

NC General Statutes - Chapter 106 Article 61 1

OPEN SPACE PRESERVATION. Reflections on the Value of Acquiring Property for Preservation Purposes

Columbia Land Trust is seeking a Conservation Lead to join its passionate team!

BLAIR COUNTY. UNDERSTANDING THE Clean and Green PROGRAM. COUNTY OF BLAIR Blair County Courthouse 423 Allegheny Street Hollidaysburg, PA

CHAPTER 82 HOUSING FINANCE

Siskiyou Land Trust. Strategic Plan Update

Shari Rodriguez Wildlife and Fisheries Biology Clemson University M. Nils Peterson, NCSU Chester Lowder, NC Farm Bureau

Clean and Green LEBANON COUNTY UNDERSTANDING THE PROGRAM

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

Voluntary Land Acquisition and Mitigation Policy For State Significant Mining, Petroleum and Extractive Industry Developments 15 DECEMBER 2014

Member consultation: Rent freedom

Transcription:

LANDOWNER REWARDS AND RISKS: FINANCIAL, CONSERVATION, FAMILY CONSIDERATIONS I n considering whether to participate in any of these compensatory programs, farmers and ranchers take into account a number of business, personal, and family factors. Some are purely financial: Is the price right in relation to the costs? In this sense, providing a conservation service for public consumption is similar to producing agricultural commodities for private markets. But a host of nonfiscal considerations also come into play when the rewards and risks of enrolling in conservation programs are closely examined. This chapter briefly reviews such personal and family-related factors. Following this, Chapter 4 concentrates on the economic rewards of participation, detailing the levels of compensation cash or tax benefits for each program. Much of this chapter is based on the perceptions of landowners captured in various research projects. This includes a mail survey of landowners in six California counties conducted in 2002-03 that examined motivations for participating in major conservation programs and perceptions of the merits of these programs (see Sokolow et al). REWARDS John Weatherford, USDA-NRCS Economic benefits are a key factor in decisions to participate in conservation programs, but they are not the only, and frequently not the dominant, consideration. What are these nonfiscal factors and how do they relate to specific programs? Conservation values In surveys and discussions farmers and ranchers express a deep concern about their land and its environmental values. One reason is their dependence on the continued productive capacities of their agricultural parcels, as expressed by a respondent to our 2002-03 survey: We are the real stewards of the land. We are on it everyday. If we don t take care of it, it won t give back to us. 25

At the same time, agricultural operators and landowners believe that their conservation credentials, created over time by working directly with the land, are more genuine than those of environmentalists and environmental programs. Although rooted in productivity, these views often extend to the habitat and other natural resource values of their property. Another survey respondent noted: If we, the owners, go to some expense and live a life to preserve countryside, wildlife, habitat, and everyone wants to drive down by road and see the cows, the flowers, the trees...it benefits the public...every day is Earth Day on my ranch. Conservation values thus are often just as or more important than economic considerations in the reasons landowners give for participating in various conservation programs. For example, decisions to take part in the USDA cost-sharing programs clearly are driven by stewardship values, considering that landowner participants are required to invest their own funds to match federal money. Likewise, decisions to sell the development rights and place easements on agricultural land involve more than purely economic incentives. A 2000 study of 46 farmers and ranchers in three California counties who sold their development rights noted that most saw the cash as a vehicle for achieving other personal objectives, including agricultural land preservation and family goals. In fact, the positives of land preservation more than overcame any concerns about easement perpetuity. Personal attachment to the easement-protected parcels was a widely held sentiment, with many landowners noting a long history of family ownership and the importance of their farms as home sites (Rilla and Sokolow, 2000). However, agricultural landowners are not of one mind in what they prize as the most important values of land conservation. Our 2002-03 survey found three different, although overlapping sets of conservation views among landowners. Some landowners stressed their role in providing food security for the future: I believe that good farmland should remain farmland. One day we won t have enough farmland to produce food if we don t take care of it. I want my land to grow crops, not houses. The ground that is not fertile can grow houses. Others gave more importance to the preservation of natural resources, including plant and wildlife habitats. Finally, the smallest number of respondents listed as their top priority the preservation of open space and restricting urban sprawl. Regulatory incentives Beyond allowing landowners to satisfy personal stewardship values, compensatory programs also may give them the resources to cope with the requirements of federal and state environmental regulations. Among all private landowners in the United States, farmers and ranchers are most affected by the public policies that seek to protect endangered species, habitat such as wetlands, and water and air resources. They are most vulnerable to regulatory imperatives because of the large landscapes they control and the nature of their agricultural practices. 26

Participation in some compensatory programs helps to soften the regulatory burdens. The USDA conservation programs offer a close fit with environmental requirements. Cost-share practices are often tailored to reducing the negative impacts of crop production and the retirement programs are intended to restore soil and other natural resources. Landowners who sell agricultural easements in some cases also serve regulatory purposes, but not because of practices on their properties. Instead the landowners are providing a conservation service to a larger area. This occurs when an easement is funded and created as mitigation for urban development elsewhere in the vicinity. By conserving in perpetuity a like or larger amount of rural land, the easement helps to ameliorate the negative environmental effects of the urban development. Family livelihoods For many agricultural landowners, maintaining a life connected to farming and the countryside is an important part of taking care of a family. Farmers, like people everywhere, want themselves and their families to have a comfortable life, to prepare for their children to be able to earn their own livelihood, and to have enough for retirement. Therefore, when considering participating in the conservation services market, landowners in our research looked carefully at how the programs would help them realize their aspirations for the future and that of their families. Realizing these aspirations is often inextricably intertwined with financial factors, since the aspirations cannot be attained without adequate cash flow. For example, farmowners ensure educational opportunities for their children by generating adequate income from farming and other sources. Table 3-1 outlines the basic financial enablers for reaching family goals. Table 3-2 goes a step further by suggesting which types of conservation programs might be most appropriate for different family goals. As Table 3-2 shows, preferential taxation programs maintain income by reducing property taxes. The reserve programs may help increase annual incomes through the rental payments they pay for not farming land, although this could be offset by the income lost from not growing certain crops. Still, an operator with land in reserve can use the time and costs freed from not cropping that property to engage in other income-producing activities. Acquisition of rights programs offer the broadest set of benefits because they make a single large, lump sum payment to landowners. Discussion with farmowners who have sold rights indicate that the cash generated one or more economic benefits - buying out the interest of others, retiring farm debt, purchasing additional land or agricultural improvements, or investing for retirement or other long-term purposes. Finally, the cost-share programs offer relatively limited economic benefits. They provide little direct cash; to get a cost-share dollar, you have to spend it. Also, participating in a program such as EQIP may produce unanticipated costs for a landowner, depending on the price of materials and project delays. However, some of these programs may pay for legally mandated 27

Table 3-1. Financial enablers of family goals Table 3-2. Programs as related to family goals 28

improvements. Also, the conservation improvements may increase productivity or reduce costs, both of which could help raise profits and increase a property s agricultural value. RISKS AND COSTS: LANDOWNER ISSUES Rewards are only one side of the story. With each of the programs, landowners must make commitments and, in most cases, establish ongoing interactions with administering agencies. Research on landowner perceptions show that many have concerns about these commitments - some would call them risks or costs - and the agencies involved. The risks come in large part from landowner perceptions about trust of government, control and finances. Many agricultural landowners believe significant risks arise from dealing with government agencies. Their argument is that the governments frequently do not live up to their agreements, impose unreasonable or unworkable requirements, and introduce a lot of unnecessary paperwork. Program managers and landowners often have similar goals regarding the conservation of agricultural land and the maintenance of farm and ranch lands, but with very different responsibilities and accountability. Essentially bureaucrats are accountable to their agency heads and policies, to their federal or state legislative bodies, and ultimately to the general public. Landowners, by contrast, are responsible to more private, immediate, close interests - their businesses, themselves, and their families. Table 3-3 identifies and explains major differences in landowner and conservation agency perspectives. The point in presenting this information is not to suggest that landowners should not protect their interests when working with agencies on conservation agreements. Rather, by recognizing that the agency bureaucrats with whom they deal are accountable to the broader public, landowners may see that their requests and requirements as reasonable and less arbitrary. Agricultural Risks Looking beyond participation in compensatory programs, a recently published workbook identifies five general categories of agricultural risk. Family and personal risk arises from the family and interpersonal dealings within it, and consequences that directly impact the life and financial well-being of families. Financial risks are most often observed by looking at the business and financial records of the agricultural operation and risks imposed by outside forces acting on cashflow or capital costs. Production risk stems from horticultural or natural occurrences that impact the quality and or quantity of the crop. Market risks occur at the point-of-sale and include things such as fluctuating prices and market access. Legal and regulatory risks refer to the risks to farm viability that laws and regulations can impose. Adapted from Tailoring Risk Management to Fit YOUR Farm: Participant s Workbook. University of California, Agricultural Issues Center, 2004. In addition to understanding the perspective of agency staff, landowners can also try to select programs that best fit with their own sets of values and perspectives. Even farmers with strong negative opinions of government find few problems with the preferential taxation approach. The Williamson Act and Farmland Security Zone programs impose no requirements on 29

landowners, other than prohibiting urban development during the duration of contracts, so paperwork and interactions with government staff are minimized. Acquisition of Rights programs lie at the other end of the spectrum as far as complexity of contracts. Large sums are often at stake and the agreements impose possibly minimal, but extremely long-term restrictions on farmowners. Landowner suspicions about working with USDA programs, in part, involve an emphasis on the regulatory and enforcement roles of federal agencies. USDA-NRCS staff, on the other hand, focus on their role as service providers, while recognizing that they are also responsible for monitoring the compliance of participating landowners with contract terms. Table 3-4 indicates program choices that may reduce landowner risks and concerns about compensatory programs. Control In addition to trust issues, landowners worry that participation in programs requires that they give up too much control over how they use their land. Some farmers believe that any restrictions on their operational autonomy, even when they are paid for this loss, violates property rights. Also, in the view of many, losing control over aspects of their land reduces the ability to realize its full productive capacity. The degree of control that agencies acquire by purchasing conservation service varies among compensatory programs. For example, the retirement programs control production decisions by restricting cultivation for a period of time. They also require farmers to establish specified practices designed to achieve program conservation objectives. On the other hand, cost-sharing programs impose less control. Although they require conservation management plans and specified conservation practices, these requirements do not affect the choice of crops to produce and usually involve only a narrow area of operations. Acquisition of rights programs run from possibly no restrictions over production decisions to more extensive requirements for practices that may have environmental effects. Most easements also limit the number and type of structures that can be added to the property. Control is also affected by monitoring requirements. Generally, the more extensive the monitoring, the greater potential for compliance issues. Financial risks Financial risks arise because enrollment in some compensatory programs limit landowners options for future economic gain. Missed profit opportunities is one way of expressing these limits, especially participation in preferential taxation and development rights programs that prohibit the development of agricultural land for more intensive urban uses. Less directly, such limits also apply to participation in the USDA cost-share and retirement programs, which assume continued agricultural use of enrolled land. 30

Table 3-3. Contentious issues: Landowner and agency views 31

32 Table 3-4. Ways to reduce risks based on landowner concerns about program requirements

Certainly, landowners with the potential for selling their agricultural parcels for development in the near future can forego considerable profits by enrolling in compensatory programs. Some landowners, however, may have unrealistic expectations of the income potential of their parcels for development. In fact, such economic opportunities are not available at any one time to most agricultural landowners in California because of how land markets operate in relation to the rate and geographical patterns of farmland conversions for urban development. Generally development in this state occurs incrementally as cities gradually expand, a result of California planning and land use policies in place for many years. As a result, only farmland that is in the immediate or near-future path of this urbanization is likely to attract urban prices. Most California farm and ranch land is located at some distance from urban expansion. Furthermore, depending on timing, the prices agricultural landowners may receive for selling development rights and acquiring restrictive easements on their properties compare favorably with the potential gains from future development. A report by the American Farmland Trust (2001) finds that the economic gains from selling an easement and investing the funds exceed the gains from selling for urban development 10 or more years in the future. Taking a more long-term look, however, can lead to other, less preservation-oriented views. Most public planning programs operate under 20-year or similar horizons, making it difficult for landowners and governments alike to project urban growth scenarios over a generation or longer. Another serious and long-term risk associated with selling development rights in perpetuity concerns the possibility that the agricultural viability of a farm or ranch restricted by an easement could be eventually compromised by land use changes on surrounding or nearby parcels. If allowed, residential development and other forms of urbanization on other properties could have negative impacts on the agricultural efficiency, and hence income, of the protected parcels. In fact, easement restricted farms can increase the residential attractiveness and market values of adjacent properties because of the open space amenities of the protected land. Two strategies can prevent such negative scenarios. One is the often effective practice of agricultural easement programs to use their resources to create large contiguous blocks of easement covered farms and ranches that reduce the exposure to nonprotected land. The other strategy involves city and county planning and land use controls that seek to prevent urban development from outflanking easement covered farms and ranches. Landowners also are concerned that restrictions on the use of the land may lower its market value, thus reducing their ability to continue to borrow operating and capital funds from banks and farm credit institutions. This is especially the case with the sale of an easement in which the removal of the development rights reduces the land s development potential. These days, however, agricultural lenders generally base their farm loans on the potential income from commodity production and not on full market value. The removal of the development rights thus does not usually affect the amount and interest on such borrowing. From the vantage point of wanting to protect farmland, selling development rights can possibly keep prices of farmland affordable for agricultural buyers. This happens when the removal of development rights maintains land values based on agricultural productivity, rather than higher urban market values. 33

Transaction Costs Finally for landowners seriously engaged in getting into a compensatory program, there are costs implicit in the application process. It takes time and effort to become acquainted with the particulars of a program, determine if they coincide with the landowner s business and family needs, fill out the necessary paperwork, and consult with program staff. Out of pocket expenses may be necessary if applicants need to confer with their professional advisors, such as attorneys and accountants, which typically occurs in completing an agricultural easement. Programs differ as to what is required in paperwork and time; Chapters 5-7 provides the application details for specific programs. Some landowners may be discouraged by these requirements to the point of not completing the application process, believing that the personal costs outweigh program benefits. Others may accept them as the necessary price to be paid for reaping the rewards of program participation. LANDOWNER COLLABORATION In most cases, applying to and participating in a compensatory program is a solitary action involving one landowner representing a single agricultural parcel. Some programs, however, seek the participation of multiple, neighboring landowners, whether at once or over time. Examples include the watershed protection priorities of some USDA programs, the Williamson Act requirement that applicant properties must be located in designated agricultural preserves, and the efforts of some agricultural easement programs to develop strategic blocks of covered land. For individual landowners, the advantages of joint or cooperative action with neighbors involve the potential sharing of risks and resources. From a public perspective, the advantages include getting more effective conservation results by covering large contiguous blocks of land rather than scattered parcels. The landowner sharing objective is implicit in two types of recently-developed collaboration that so far have not been applied in California. Both are voluntary devices that allow landowners, through common planning and action, to combine the conservation of large landscapes with some economic return: Agricultural Preservation and Development Associations. Primarily found in Colorado, APDAs are either profit or nonprofit organizations that allow landowners to both combine resources and negotiate in a strengthened position with planning agencies (see Carlson). Landpooling. In a legal partnership, neighboring landowners pool assets and liabilities to reduce the uncertainty and negative affects of speculation (see Landpool Administrators web site). Of course, landowners in a neighborhood can cooperate on common issues in a more informal fashion, exchanging information and coordinating their actions. 34

OTHER REWARDS: OPPORTUNITIES TO INFLUENCE PROGRAMS A different kind of reward for landowners involves the opportunity to influence how compensatory conservation programs are managed and implemented. The programs generally are sensitive to the concerns and circumstances of their enrollees. However, beyond formal enrollment and involvement in conventional agricultural organizations such as local farm bureaus and commodity groups, there are participatory opportunities for farmers and ranchers to work with program managers on policy and administrative issues. Most programs have advisory or even governance mechanisms that are open to farmers and ranchers with strong conservation interests. Like program enrollment, getting involved in these influence mechanisms is voluntary and depends on landowner initiative. Service on advisory or governance boards is not entirely cost-free. There are time and study obligations. Furthermore, the rewards are more general and less self-serving than the economic incentives for enrolling in a program, since they involve working on broad issues of program design and implementation. For landowners who want to make a difference in the land conservation area, such public contributions can result in substantial personal satisfaction. A brief review of both the formal and informal opportunities follows. USDA conservation programs Perhaps the most extensive and formalized arrangements for getting landowner advice is provided by the USDA cost-share and retirement programs administered by the Natural Resources Conservation Service. Mandated by federal law, these participatory bodies in California include the State Technical Advisory Committee (TAC), local workgroups, and stakeholder groups. Membership is open to anyone who applies and is broadly defined. Several thousand Californians participate in the meetings of these groups. Most are agricultural landowners, but they also include representatives of public and nonprofit conservation agencies. The 500-member state TAC meets quarterly in locations throughout the state. Members are informed about changes in programs and advise the NRCS State Conservationist and staff on ranking criteria and other program matters. The state group has several subcommittees for EQIP and other specific programs. Many more people participate at the local level in workgroups and stakeholder groups that work with NRCS district conservationists on local funding priorities. 35

Resource conservation districts California s 103 resource conservation districts (RCDs), operating in most agricultural areas of the state, offer another participation opportunity for conservation-minded landowners. Several hundred persons, many of them farmers and ranchers, serve on district governing boards. Most of the 5 to 9 member bodies are appointed by county boards of supervisors, although few districts are formally part of county government. Created as a form of special district under California local government law, the RCDs are strongly landowner-oriented in their mission and activities. Their core functions include educating landowners and the public about resource conservation, helping landowners implement specific projects, and coordinating resource conservation efforts. In several respects, the RCDs parallel the NRCS. Originally known as soil conservation districts, they were created by states during the 1930s to provide a landowner complement to USDA activities. That close relationship continues, with NRCS field staff often providing technical assistance, although many districts have their own professional staffs. RCDs are also a vehicle for landowner participation through Resource Conservation and Development Councils (RC&Ds). Land trusts Contact information for NRCS committees Individuals interested in joining NRCS advisory groups can contact a local NRCS office. Members of the State Technical Advisory Committee receive notification of meetings which occur about four times a year. Information on the statutory responsibilities of the State Technical Advisory Committee is available at http://policy.nrcs.usda./gov/scripts/ lpsiis.dll/m/m_440_501_b_10.htm The California meeting schedule can be found at http://www.ca.nrcs.usda.gov/technical/stac.html. Land trusts are nonprofit organizations that manage acquisition of development rights programs. They are largely volunteer agencies with few, if any, professional staff and they rely greatly on their boards of directors and others. With as many as a dozen or more members, the boards become involved in most aspects of the programs, especially using their personal knowledge of local agricultural communities to make initial contact with landowners potentially interested in selling easements, and working with them to negotiate and complete transactions. Agricultural land trusts that focus on putting farms and ranches under easement usually have boards composed of a majority or many agricultural landowners. Examples include the Yolo Land Trust, Marin Agricultural Land Trust, and the statewide California Rangeland Trust. Beyond their citizen boards, some land trusts also benefit from the contributions of volunteers. The largest participatory opportunities are in stewardship work, particularly the periodic monitoring usually required by the deeded restrictions of easement-covered properties. Some land trusts rely primarily on trained volunteers for this work. 36

References American Farmland Trust. 2001. Winning the Development Lottery: A Landowner s Guide to Agricultural Conservation Easements and the Development Potential of Farmland in California s Central Valley. California Department of Conservation. http://www.conserv.ca.gov/dlrp/lca/index.htm California Department of Conservation. 1989. Land in the Balance: Williamson Act Costs, Benefits and Options. Part 2 A Short History of the Williamson Act. Carlson, David. 2003. Agricultural Preservation and Development Associations. Pp. 221-232 in Compensating Landowners for Conserving Agricultural Land: Papers from a California Conference. Community Studies Extension and Agricultural Issues Center, University of California, Davis. December. http://www.aic.ucdavis.edu Klonsky, Karen et al. 2003. Farmer Views of Farmland Conservation and Stewardship in California. Pp. 85-89 in Compensating Landowners for Conserving Agricultural Land: Papers from a California Conference. Community Studies Extension and Agricultural Issues Center, University of California, Davis. December. http://www.aic.ucdavis.edu Landpool Administrators, www.landpooling.com. Rilla, Ellen, and Alvin D. Sokolow. 2000. California Farmers and Conservation Easements: Motivations, Experiences, and Perceptions in Three Counties. University of California Agricultural Issues Center, Davis. Research Paper 4. December. Sokolow, Alvin D., Joan Wright, Nora DeCuir, and Mica Bennett. 2003. What California Farmland Owners Like and Don t Like about Compensatory Programs for Conservation. Pp. 73-84 in Compensating Landowners for Conserving Agricultural Land: Papers from a California Conference. Community Studies Extension and Agricultural Issues Center, University of California, Davis. December. http://www.aic.ucdavis.edu. 37

38