Land Policies and Land Reforms in India: Progress and Implications for the Future

Similar documents
With about three-fifth of India s workforce still in agriculture,

The Effects of Land Title Registration on Tenure Security, Investment and Production

Land II. Esther Duflo. April 13,

14.74 Foundations of Development Policy Spring 2009

Sorting based on amenities and income

Affordable Housing Policy. Economics 312 Martin Farnham

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY IN LANDHOLDING DISTRIBUTION OF RURAL BANGLADESH

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

LAND MARKETS IN UGANDA: INCIDENCE, IMPACT AND EVOLUTION OVER TIME

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Negative Gearing and Welfare: A Quantitative Study of the Australian Housing Market

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers?

Land-Use Regulation in India and China

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

MARKET VALUE BASIS OF VALUATION

MULTIPLE CHALLENGES REAL ESTATE APPRAISAL INDUSTRY FACES QUALITY CONTROL. Issues. Solution. By, James Molloy MAI, FRICS, CRE

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Do Family Wealth Shocks Affect Fertility Choices?

EITF Issue No EITF Issue No Working Group Report No. 1, p. 1

This article is relevant to the Diploma in International Financial Reporting and ACCA Qualification Papers F7 and P2

Access to Land and Development 1 Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet University of California at Berkeley August 2005

Ind AS 115 Impact on the real estate sector and construction companies

National Association for several important reasons: GOING BY THE BOOK

In light of this objective, Global Witness is providing feedback on key sections of the 6 th draft of the national land policy:

Motivation: Do land rights matter?

POLICY BRIEFING. ! Housing and Poverty - the role of landlords JRF research report

Waiting for Affordable Housing in NYC

Chapter 1 Economics of Net Leases and Sale-Leasebacks

MONETARY POLICY AND HOUSING MARKET: COINTEGRATION APPROACH

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

SSAP 14 STATEMENT OF STANDARD ACCOUNTING PRACTICE 14 LEASES

DRAFT REPORT. Boudreau Developments Ltd. Hole s Site - The Botanica: Fiscal Impact Analysis. December 18, 2012

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount?

An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 40. Investment Property

Viability and the Planning System: The Relationship between Economic Viability Testing, Land Values and Affordable Housing in London

Emerging Policy Issues in Indian Agriculture: Land Acquisition

LeaseCalcs: The Great Wall

International Accounting Standard 17 Leases. Objective. Scope. Definitions IAS 17

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States

The joint leases project change is coming

The impacts of land title registration: evidence from a pilot in Rwanda. Daniel Ali Klaus Deininger Markus Goldstein Preliminary: Please do not cite

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

Member consultation: Rent freedom

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

Agreements for the Construction of Real Estate

Research Note SOCIO - ECONOMIC INDUCEMENTS IN LAND MARKET : CASE STUDY OF UTTAR PRADESH STATE IN INDIA. Gyanendra Mani V.K. Pandey.

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY JUNE 14, 2017

LKAS 17 Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 17

Leases: Overview of the new guidance

An Overview of the Proposed Bonus Depreciation Regulations under Section 168(k)

THE LEGAL AND FINANCIAL FRAMEWORK OF AN EFFICIENT PRIVATE RENTAL SECTOR: THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

REAL ESTATE REFORMS: THE UK S MOST POPULAR PROPERTY POLICY IDEAS MFS

LEIBNIZ INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES

Rental market underdevelopment in Central Europe: Micro (Survey) I and Macro (DSGE) perspective

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

Land Use Rights and Productivity: Insights from a 2006 Rural Household Survey

Cube Land integration between land use and transportation

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Housing Transfer Taxes and Household Mobility: Distortion on the Housing or Labour Market? Christian Hilber and Teemu Lyytikäinen

In December 2003 the Board issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

Land Rights and Land Reform

THE IMPACT OF RESIDENTIAL REAL ESTATE MARKET BY PROPERTY TAX Zhanshe Yang 1, a, Jing Shan 2,b

Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB)

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

Housing Costs and Policies

Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs

Leases. (a) the lease transfers ownership of the asset to the lessee by the end of the lease term.

China Centre for Land Policy Research, Nanjing Agricultural University, China. Department of Social Sciences, Wageningen University, the Netherlands

This version includes amendments resulting from IFRSs issued up to 31 December 2009.

Comparative Study on Affordable Housing Policies of Six Major Chinese Cities. Xiang Cai

Course Number Course Title Course Description

In December 2003 the Board issued a revised IAS 17 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

Extending the Right to Buy

In December 2003 the Board issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

The Financial Accounting Standards Board

Institutional Analysis of Condominium Management System in Amhara Region: the Case of Bahir Dar City

Exposure Draft 64 January 2018 Comments due: June 30, Proposed International Public Sector Accounting Standard. Leases

Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property

Board Meeting Handout ACCOUNTING FOR CONTINGENCIES September 6, 2007

In December 2003 the IASB issued a revised IAS 40 as part of its initial agenda of technical projects.

Analysing lessee financial statements and Non-GAAP performance measures

.01 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment for investment property and related disclosure requirements.

Dear members of the International Accounting Standards Board,

2018 Accounting & Auditing Update P R E S E N T E D B Y : D A N I E L L E Z I M M E R M A N & A N D R E A S A R T I N

Is terrorism eroding agglomeration economies in Central Business Districts?

Solutions to Questions

Going global. Trouble ahead. Ongoing major projects. Where next?

Topic 842 Technical Corrections Summary of Comments Received

Implementing the New Lease Guidance

Shaping Housing and Community Agendas

Single Payments of the CAP: Where Do the Rents Go?

Access to Land and Building Permits

Transcription:

Land Policies and Land Reforms in India: Progress and Implications for the Future Klaus Deininger The World Bank and Hari Nagarajan National Council of Applied Economic Policy Research Prepared for Presentation at tbe Brookings-NCAER India Policy Forum 2007 New Delhi July 17-18, 2007 Conference Draft Not for Citation

Land policies and land reforms in India: Progress and implications for the future Klaus Deininger 1, Hari K. Nagarajan 2 1 World Bank, Washington DC, USA 2 National Council for Applied Economic Research, New Delhi, India

Land policies and land reforms in India: Progress, and implications for the future Abstract: Perhaps not surprisingly, given the serious and harmful long term consequences of the land ownership inequality established and maintained under colonial rule, land policy in India has been heavily focused on state-led land redistribution. We argue that greater reliance on markets can help achieve original land reform goals. Data from the 1982/99 ARIS/REDS are used to demonstrate that (i) the productivityimpact of rental markets is very positive; (ii) they transfer land to the poor on a large scale; and (iii) statelevel rental restrictions have a large negative impact on supply of land for rental. These data also show that sales markets have been much less biased against the poor than often argued. To prevent an unraveling of the gains from land reforms, provide the basis for well functioning land markets, and avoid that insecure property rights develop into an obstacle to future growth and poverty reduction, more attention to land administration is needed. A review of different states experience in computerizing their land records and automating registries highlights differential progress (including scope for leapfrogging by latecomers), helps identify the elements of a comprehensive system, and points towards ways of addressing them in a way building on India s comparative advantage. The paper concludes by drawing out implications for policy and research. 1. Motivation and background Land reforms have for a long time constituted a central element of India s policy for rural poverty reduction and growth. However, given that most of the relevant policies were put in place long time ago and that high levels of economic growth continue to profoundly transform India s economic landscape but also create new demands for land policy, questions on the continued adequacy of such policies and a potential need to refocus overall policy and implementation have emerged. A key justification for India s land reform policies was that (i) markets on their own will not accomplish the redistribution of land to the poor and marginalized that is necessary to overcome the legacy of deprivation, increase productivity, and move towards greater equality of opportunity and that (ii) bureaucratic action can accomplish this goal more effectively and at a lower cost. While this is likely to have been the case true when such measures had been conceived, the pace of land reform implementation has slowed considerably while economic growth and government policies to help backward regions advance have helped to attenuate many of the market imperfections that provided the justification for government intervention. Despite restrictions on their functioning in many states, markets for rental of land have picked up considerably. However, empirical evidence on the extent to which they contribute to increased productivity and the impact of policies on their functioning remains limited. Three observations suggest that more detailed exploration of this issue may be of relevance. First, with about 15 million farm households participating in land rental even according to existing data, the number of households who access land through rental markets every year exceeds that of those who obtained land through land reforms, defined as either tenancy reform or redistribution of ceiling surplus land, throughout India s entire post-independence period. Second, economic development is both a cause and a consequence of increased demand for land transactions. However, in marked contrast to China, where, 2

despite a much more egalitarian distribution of land, the amount of land rental increased more than fourfold between 1995 and 2001, the amount of rental transactions in India shows a steady and secular decline since 1971, with the share of households involved in land rental in 2001 (11.6%) less than half of that 30 years earlier (25.8%). As in China land rental has been shown to be not only critical for farmers to take up non-agricultural employment but also to be associated with productivity increases of about 60%, this could indeed have far-reaching consequences. Although more detailed analysis will be required, the fact that a recent survey shows that 29% of owners leave all or part of their land fallow during the main growing season in Karnataka and Tamil Nadu while 15% do so in Bihar -all states where tenancy is either explicitly prohibited or made impossible by the fact that tenants acquire permanent rights to the land they cultivate- is consistent with the notion that such legislation could indeed have non-trivial productivity impacts the magnitude of which is likely to increase over time. In this context, this paper has tow goals. First, noting that much of the debate has been based on ideological prejudice more than on rigorous and representative quantitative evidence, we use unique household-level data from NCAER to provide evidence on the functioning of land rental and some extent sales markets to assess not only the extent to which these contributed to higher productivity and improved land access but also how reform-related regulations have affected operation of land markets and the associated economic outcomes. Second, as markets depend on the extent to which property rights are clear, well defined, and information on them is available and their transfer and enforcement is possible at low cost, we assess the extent to which India s system of land administration provides the elements needed for an optimum functioning of markets with the goal to draw lessons from advanced states on the extent to which IT-related opportunities can help to make land reform policies more market-friendly while at the same time improving overall service delivery in the land sector. 2. Do rental restrictions affect productivity of land use? In this section, we describe the rationale for and characteristics of rental restrictions in India, sketch out a framework that allows us to make predictions on their impact, test the extent to which these notion are borne out by actual data, and draw conclusions for policy. 2.1 Origins and nature of rural tenancy restrictions in India Under colonial rule, the main goal of India s land administration system was to obtain government revenue. The de facto award of land rights to revenue collectors (zamindars) in large parts of the country has consequences that affect development to this day (Banerjee and Iyer 2005). Agrarian reform was thus at the top of the immediate post-independence agenda and the fact that land was put under the competence of states rather than the Center led to considerable diversity in the timing, substance, and 3

implementation of reforms across states. Abolition of rent-collecting intermediaries was tackled swiftly and successfully virtually everywhere. However, ceiling legislation -aiming to legislate a maximum land holding and force owners to dispose of all that was owned beyond this limit- and tenancy reform -which had the goal of limiting the rent to be paid for land and prohibiting tenant evictions- took a long time. 1 The existence of wide variations in legislation across states provides ample scope to analyze the impact of such policies on outcomes. To do so, we use the share of households who benefited from key policies as an indicator for policy-induced constraints to the operation of rental markets. Specifically, we construct for each state the share of households who were awarded tenancy rights and the share of ceiling surplus area that was actually transferred to beneficiaries. 2 As none of the Indian states permit sub-leasing of lands to which tenants had received permanent rights and most states also impose restrictions on transfers of land received in the course of implementing ceiling legislation, this is proxies for direct restrictions on the operation of land rental markets. Both figures provide an approximation for a state government s level of implementation effort, a variable that is exogenous to households decisions (Banerjee et al. 2002). A detailed look at the time dimension of this effort allows a number of conclusions (Kaushik 2005). First, even without accounting for abolition of intermediaries, land reform was a major effort; up to 2000, it resulted in the transfer of almost 10 mn ha, 2.5 mn ha via ceiling surplus redistribution and 7.35 mn ha via tenancy legislation. 3 However, after a spurt in the 1970s and early 1980s, implementation slowed down; in fact between 1995/96 and 2003/04, i.e. for almost a decade, progress almost completely halted. 4 2.2 International evidence and conceptual framework Although empirical evidence on the impact of rent ceilings and other forms of tenancy control in rural areas is limited, the issue has been analyzed in urban contexts where rent control is a textbook example for policies that transfer resources from landlords to sitting tenants in the short term but that will be associated with inefficiencies in the medium to long run (Arnott 2003). The key reason is that, by fixing rents below their equilibrium level, controls reduce the supply of new housing (or maintenance of existing 1 The fact that implementation started in earnest only after 1972 allowed landlords to prepare by resuming self cultivation, evicting tenants or transforming them into wage workers, or implement spurious subdivisions. Using census figures, Appu (1997) estimates that, to avoid having to give rights to tenants, landlords evicted about 30 mn tenants or about one third of the total agriculturally active population, similar to evidence from other countries with similar policies (Deininger 2003). 2 We use area rather than beneficiaries because in some cases ceiling surplus land was distributed to a collective entity such as a cooperative so that the number of beneficiaries would be misleading. Also, the existence of large discrepancies between the amount of land expropriated and actually distributed -which is due to the fact that in some cases land that had been distributed could not occupied by beneficiaries or was taken back after some time- led us to focus on land actually distributed. 3 The amount of land involved is much larger than what was redistributed in other Asian land reforms such as Japan (2 mn has), Korea (0.58 mn has) and Taiwan (0.24 mn has). In terms of total area distributed, this puts India on par with Mexico which, in a much more land-abundant setting, and starting in 1917, managed to distribute slightly more than 13 mn ha (Deininger 2003). 4 The increment in ceiling surplus land transferred during the period amounted to only 10,800 ha which is only about one tenth of the land declared ceiling surplus which had not been distributed. The fact that all the remainder remains tied up in litigation suggests that further progress in achieving redistribution of ceiling land could be slow -it would take almost 90 years to dispose of remaining ceiling surplus cases if the current pace is maintained- and that, by clogging up the court system and preventing it from quickly dispensing justice in other urgent matters, the ceiling legislation may impose external effects beyond land rental markets (Moog 1997). 4

stock) due to artificially reduced prices (Gyourko and Linneman 1990), thus making access to rental more difficult thereafter (Basu and Emerson 2000). With a constant or decreasing number of beneficiaries and an increasing number of new entrants who need to access to land in distorted markets, social cost of maintaining land rental restrictions will increase over time (Glaeser 2002). Identifying other policies that can be better targeted and have fewer undesirable side-effects is thus desirable (Munch and Svarer 2002). As, in rural areas, the impact of rental restrictions goes beyond the price effects on which urban literature has focused, it may be more far-reaching. First, due to labor market imperfections, the way in which rural land is used will have an clear impact on productive efficiency (Binswanger et al. 1995). Second, housing supply will be more inelastic than that of productive land as owners can not revert to own- or wage laborbased cultivation as in the case of agricultural land (Appu 1997). Third, as rural rents are an in-kind output share, contract terms will be less flexible than urban ones, limiting the scope for circumventing them by adjusting rental rates (Basu and Emerson 2003). Finally, rights given to tenants are heritable but non-transferable and still require rent payment to the landlord, thus reducing both parties incentives for land-related investments and the scope to increase allocative efficiency through sub-leasing. To explore the impact of such restrictions on rental markets, we use a simple model where a key rationale for producers to enter land markets is the desire to adjust for differences in their existing endowments of land and family labor. Let household i be endowed with fixed amounts of labor ( L i ) and land ( A i ), and agricultural ability ( α ). Agricultural production follows a production function f(α i,, l i,a,a i ) with standard i properties, i.e. f >0, f <0 with respect to all arguments and f la >0. Relative land scarcity, together with the cost of supervising labor (Frisvold 1994) makes wage-labor based cultivation undesirable in equilibrium (Binswanger et al. 1995), implying that households allocate their labor endowment between farming their own land (l i,a ) and off-farm employment (l i,o ) at an exogenous wage ( w ). Renting of land incurs transaction costs TC in for renting-in and TC out for renting-out because of the need to obtain information on market conditions, to negotiate and enforce payments, and the presence of regulations that restrict transferability or completely outlaw certain contract types. Transaction costs are assumed to be proportional to the size of land transferred. With households able to structure rental contracts in a way that allows those lacking liquidity to enter into arrangements, thus allowing to defer rental payments until the harvest, household i s decision problem is to choose A i, l i,a and l i,o to solve l i, a Max, l i, o, A i pf ( α, l, A ) + wl I [( A A )( r + TC )] + I [( A A )( r TC )] (1) i i, a i i, o in i i s.t. l i,a +l i,o L (1a) l i,a, l i,o, A i 0 (1b) in out i i out 5

where p is the price of agricultural goods, r is the rental rate, A i is the operational land size, I in is a out indicator variable for rent-in (=1 for rent-in, 0 otherwise), I is an indicator for rent-out (=1 for rentout, and 0 otherwise), TC in and TC out are transaction costs, and all other variables are as defined above. From the first order conditions, we can derive three propositions that can be tested empirically. 5 Proposition 1: The amount of land rented in (out) is strictly increasing (decreasing) in households agricultural ability, α i, and strictly decreasing (increasing) in the land endowment A i. Land rental will transfer land to efficient, but land-poor producers, thereby contributing to higher levels of productivity and more efficient factor use in the economy. Proposition 2: The presence of transaction costs defines two critical ability levels α l (TC out,..) and α u (TC in,..) such that households with ability α i [α l, α u ] will remain in autarky. Any increase in TC in or TC out will expand the autarky range, thus reducing the number of producers participating in rental markets and the number of efficiency-enhancing land transactions. Compared to a situation with no transaction cost, this will decrease productivity and social welfare. Proposition 3: Increases of the exogenously given wage for off-farm employment will imply that higher amounts of land are transacted in rental markets as households with low agricultural ability who join the off-farm labor market will supply more land. This leads to a decrease in the equilibrium rental rate which will prompt high-ability workers to rent in more land and specialize in agricultural production. From the model, producers land market participation depends on their marginal productivity in autarky, MP( A )compared to the net rental paid r in (T) or received r out (T) as a function of transaction costs. These variables define three regimes (rent out, in, and autarky) that can be estimated in an ordered probit model. 99 Prob(y 1 i = ) = Φ{ εi < η0 + η1s + η2z + η3d β0 β1α β2a β3l β4k β5e β6o} 99 Prob(y 2 i = ) = Φ{ η0 + η1s + η2z + η3d β0 β1α β2a β3l β4k β5e β6o< εi 99 < δ0 + δ1s + δ2z + δ3d β0 β1α β2a β3l β4k β5e β6o} 99 Prob(y = 3 ) =Φ{ε > i i i δ0 + δ1s + δ2z + δ3d β0 β1α β2a β3l β4k β5e β6o} (2) Variables we expect to affect marginal productivity are agricultural ability (α) which we derive from a panel production function, a dummy for landlessness, the log of the land endowment for A, labor as proxied by the number of members aged 14-60 and below 14 for L, the value of assets for K, the head s age to proxy experience, a dummy for primary education to represent human capital E, and mean village income O to represent off-farm opportunities. Transaction cost of land rental is affected by producer s 5 For a more detailed derivation see (Deininger and Jin 2006) 6

caste (Z), a time dummy (D 99 ), and policy (S), proxied by the share of households recognized via tenancy reform, the share of area distributed under ceiling legislation, or the number of tenancy laws. The propositions from the model allow predictions on signs of individual coefficients. Factor equalization (prop. 1) implies that rental markets will transfer land to more productive producers (β 1 >0) with lower levels of land endowments (β 2 <0) and more family labor (β 3 >0). Wealth bias in rental markets, possibly due to credit market imperfections, translates into β 4 >0. Diversification effects (prop. 3) imply that producers with better education and off farm opportunities will be less likely to rent in land (β 5 <0; β 6 <0). Proposition 2 implies that, by moving the cut-off points where producers shift from renting out to autarky and from autarky to renting in, respectively, rental market restrictions expand the range of autarky but do not affect producers marginal product. 6 We thus expect η 1 >0 and δ 1 <0, respectively. By the same logic, higher transaction costs for producers from scheduled and backward castes imply η 2 >0, and δ 2 <0 while a reduction over time in transaction costs due to better access to information implies η 3 <0 and δ 3 >0. 2.3 Data sources and descriptive evidence The data used here and below come from two rounds of NCAER s ARIS/REDS survey conducted in 1982 and 1999, respectively. This survey, the first rounds of which were implemented in 1968-71 covers all of India s major states. The 1982 sample covers some 5,000 households (Foster and Rosenzweig 1996) and adding replacements and splits yields about 7,500 households in 1999 (Foster and Rosenzweig 2004). Table 1 presents household characteristics by rental participation status (rent in, rent out, or autarky). It highlights a large increase in the level of land market activity over the period; from 5.3% and 2% for renting out and renting in, respectively, in 1982, the share of market participants has increased to 10.7% and 4.1%, in 1999. 7 Descriptive figures also support the propositions from our model and the notion of better rental market functioning in the second, as compared to the first period. Comparing the per capita land endowment for land owners who either remained in autarky (0.51 ha and 0.36 ha in 1982 and 1999, respectively), rented in (0.28 ha and 0.20 ha), or rented out (0.68 ha and 0.64 ha) illustrates that, in both periods, rental provided opportunities for land-scarce and labor-abundant households to gain access to land. Land markets transferred land from households with more educated and female heads to male headed ones with less education. The share of landless who had gained access to land through rental 6 It is intuitive that rental restrictions will directly affect whether or not households participate but, unless there are selectivity issue, are unlikely to affect producers marginal productivity. Indeed testing for selectivity of rental market participation, by including rental restrictions in the marginal product equation as well, did not produce conclusive results. 7 While this is a large change, the level of rental market activity increased more rapidly, and in a shorter period, in other Asian countries such as China or Vietnam, despite the fact that the more egalitarian land ownership distribution in these countries would put greater limits on the potential of land markets to equalize operational holdings than in India. In Vietnam, the share of households renting in increased form 3.8% to 15.8% in the 5-year period between 1993 and 1998 (Deininger and Jin 2007). In China, the same figure increased from 2.3% in 1996 to 9.4 in 2001 (Deininger and Jin 2005). 7

markets increased from 12% in the first to 37% in the second period, suggesting a marked expansion of outreach towards this group over time. Noting that our sample represents about 130 mn rural households, in 1999 about 15 mn households -a quarter of them landless- were able to use markets as a means to get access to land. This is not only much larger than the number of those who got access to land through land reform but also highlights that, given the magnitudes involved, even policies with modest impact on the functioning of land rental markets could have implications for a large number of households. Comparing levels of consumption and assets for households who differ in the nature of their land market participation reinforces the notion that rental provides opportunities for poor segments of the population to access productive resources and thereby improve their well-being. The value of all assets owned by households renting in 1999 was, with Rs. 33,839, more than 25% below the average, compared to asset ownership that is similar to the mean for autarkic households and about 33% higher than the mean for those renting out, supporting the notion that it is the asset-poor who benefit from the access to land which rental markets provide. The narrowing of the gap between rent-in and average households with respect to per capita expenditure is consistent with the hypothesis of land markets making a positive contribution to the livelihood of participants. Finding significant differences in the composition of the asset portfolio between rent-in and rent-out households, with the former having relatively more of their wealth in farming and livestock, and the latter in off-farm and financial assets, is not too surprising. The high share of renters engaging in (agricultural) wage employment suggests that land rental provides wage laborers with ways to earn additional income. The fact that -in contrast to 1982- non-farm self employment is much higher among rent-in households than either the mean or those who remained in autarky suggests that land rental is not an obstacle to participation in the rural non-farm economy. 2.4 Econometric results Results from ordered probit estimation of the rental market participation equation using the pooled sample for 1982 and 1999 and with and without ability which is defined only for those producing in both periods, are reported in table 2. The pairs of columns correspond to policy variables, i.e. recognition of tenants, distribution of ceiling land, and tenancy laws. To interpret these, recall the coding of 1 for rent-out, 2 for autarky, and 3 for rent-in regimes so that positive coefficients increase the probability of renting out. The highly significant coefficient on ability implies that, as expected, rental markets improve productivity of land use by transferring land from less to more efficient producers. The magnitude is large; according to the estimates, the probability for the most efficient household in the sample to rent in is more than 8

double that for the average household. 8 There is also a strong factor equalization effect. Higher land and lower labor endowments -especially for 14-60 year olds- increase the propensity to supply land to the rental market, support that, by transferring land to labor-rich but land-poor households, markets allow gainful employment of rural labor. The large and significant coefficient of the landless dummy suggests that rental is important for landless households to access land. Landless producer s propensity to rent is, at 5.4 to 8.6 points above that for land owners almost double that of the former. Lack of significance for the coefficient on total assets suggests that rental markets are not biased in favor of the wealthy. 9 A strong diversification effect also emerges. Completion of primary education by the head increases (decreases) the propensity to rent out (in) land, by about 2.1% and 1.1%, respectively. Mean village income increases the tendency to rent out, too, implying that as the level of income increases, households will be more likely to move out of agriculture, supply land to the rental market, and allow those remaining behind to increase their holdings and income levels, as is also observed in other countries, e.g. China. Regarding the lower bound equation, regressions suggest that policy restrictions will lead to a significant and quantitatively large reduction of land supply to rental markets. Estimated effects are weakest for the number of laws (columns 5 and 6) and strongest for recognition of tenants (col. 1 and 2), consistent with the notion that implementation is more important than mere legislation and that landlords will be less willing to rent out if doing so can attenuate their property rights or if there are limits on their ability to negotiate the amount of rent. The share of land affected by redistribution of ceiling land is in the middle between these two, consistent with expectations that ceiling legislation poses less of a threat than tenancy regulation -as the latter applies to all market participants irrespective of their holding size- and enforcing it is more politically controversial and administratively complex than implementing tenancy legislation. The 1999 dummy illustrates that, over time, land rental supply increased significantly. To quantify the impact of policy restrictions we compute, for every household, the predicted probability to rent out with actual values for all right hand side variables and with the tenancy restriction variable taking a value of zero. Taking the difference between these two values as a measure for the impact of tenancy restrictions suggests that their removal could lead to a considerable increase in renting out, by between 40% and 70%. Turning to the (upper) bound between autarky and renting in, positive coefficients on all policy variables suggest that these also depressed demand, making it more difficult for households to obtain land through rental. Across policy variables, those relating to the intensity of enforcement are again more significant; in fact the number of laws, while of the expected sign, is not different from zero at conventional levels. In 8 While lack of data on profits before and after rental participation makes it difficult to assess the net impact on productivity, evidence from China, where rental helped increase productivity gains by some 60% (Deininger and Jin 2006), suggest that these can be large. 9 Inclusion of an interaction between the time dummy and asset ownership (not reported) suggests that land rental markets had been biased in favor of the wealthy in 1982 but that, presumably due to better credit market access in the study areas, this bias had disappeared by 1999. 9

most equations, coefficients are bigger for the upper as compared to the lower bound, suggesting that the impact of policy-induced restrictions will be larger on the demand side. Simulations suggest that removal of tenancy restriction could double participation rates by rent-in households. Backward and scheduled castes are more likely to remain in autarky and over time, the size of the autarky area has decreased, i.e. land rental markets have become more active. While this is encouraging sign and suggests that time may partly offset undesirable impacts of rental regulation, the magnitude of the coefficients is small; estimated coefficients imply that almost a century will be required to offset these effects. Time is thus unlikely to eliminate the negative effects of tenancy regulation or do so in an equitable manner, in line with case study evidence suggesting that circumventing legislation is easier for the rich than the poor (Yugandhar 1996, Thangaraj 2004). Interacting policy variables with producers estimated productive efficiency (not reported) allows more detailed exploration of rental restrictions impact on efficiency with results reinforcing the notion that rental restrictions significantly curtail efficiency of land use by preventing land access by the most efficient producers. 2.5 Policy implications In rural India, there is an increasing recognition of the importance of land rental markets to bring land to more productive uses while at the same time providing a basis for development of the rural non-farm economy. Although the continued need for restrictions on the operation of land rental markets has been debated at an abstract level in numerous case studies, quantitative evidence of its impact has been scant, giving rise to a debate that is highly ideological in nature. Use of a national sample, jointly with crossstate variation in tenancy legislation, allows us to provide evidence on the impact of rental markets in general and restrictions on the operation of such markets in particular. Contrary to what is often assumed, our data suggest that, by allowing higher ability individuals to access land and equalizing factor ratios, rental markets improve productivity and equity. The level of activity has increased significantly over time and wealth bias that had characterized such markets earlier evaporated as the economy has diversified. While land markets make an essential contribution to the emergence of the non-agricultural economy, rental restrictions limit the level of market activity and the ability of the most productive producers to access more land, thus reducing overall welfare. These results, which are in line with case study evidence from a number of states, highlight the importance of taking action on eliminating rental market restrictions, as articulated in the Government s 10 th 5-year plan (Government of India 2002) and reiterated more forcefully in the documents circulated in preparation for the 11 th plan. 10 10 freedom in leasing of land, both 'leasing in' and 'leasing out' will help generate income for both lessee and lessor/contractor. A legislation needs to be enacted to facilitate the land utilisation by making land transactions easier and facilitating leasing and contract farming. (Government of India 2002, p. 528). Note that political resistance to abolition of tenancy restrictions can likely be minimized by taking sitting 10

These results will also be of great relevance for neighboring countries, many of which have equally restrictive land rental policies that are likely to have similar impacts. 3. Do land sales markets harm the poor through distress sales? Although less restricted than land rental, it is often argued that, due to imperfections in other markets, land sales can lead to outcomes that are undesirable both under equity and efficiency considerations. We review the underlying argument and review the available evidence from the data at hand. 3.1 Motivation Few interventions have been as passionately debated, and subject to a larger number of policy restrictions than the operation of land sales markets. Proponents argue that the ability to sell land in a freely operating market is crucial not only to maximize productivity of land use and facilitate optimal resource allocation but also for financial market development, by allowing use of land as collateral and thus a reduction of the cost of providing credit. Government should, it is argued, strive to set a framework within which land markets can operate and otherwise adopt a laissez-faire approach. Opponents retort that land is more than just a commodity and that, with multiple imperfections in other markets, free operation of land markets will often not enhance efficiency. They maintain that historic inequalities in land access, and a danger of distress sales or speculative acquisition, make concentration of land likely and that, unless government intervenes or even prohibits land sales, sales markets will yield undesirable social and economic effects. While theoretical models that put land sales markets into the general context of a household s choice of an optimum asset portfolio can generate widely divergent predictions, empirical evidence to assess the extent to which these correspond to actual outcomes -and key underlying factors- is often scant. In fact, as land sales markets are normally very thin, large or sufficiently long samples will be required to be able to observe causes and consequences of land market participation. Existing studies are often based on comparatively small samples (Sarap 1995, Lanjouw and Stern 1998) or rely on retrospective information (Baland et al. 2007). The implied selectivity and lack of initial characteristics makes it in many cases difficult for analysis to go beyond simple descriptive statistics or transition matrices with little scope to help identify underlying factors and thus provide much-needed insight to enlighten the policy debate. 3.2 Conceptual framework and estimation strategy If households do not face subsistence or borrowing constraints that would otherwise prevent them from fully insuring against risk, everybody has access to the same set of information, and switching transaction tenants welfare into account and by proceeding in a stepwise manner, starting with states characterized by high agricultural potential, and by carefully documenting the results from doing so. 11

partners is costless, the market for land sales will not be different from that for land rental. Demand for land would be determined by producers ability to make best use of the land in farming and relative land endowments and market transactions will enhance social welfare by allowing small producers with higher levels of productivity to bid land away from large and less productive land owners (Zimmerman and Carter 1999). Land prices would equal the net present value of the stream of profits from the best available land use, and potential buyers would be indifferent between renting land and purchasing it. Policy-makers concern about land markets leading to outcomes that may be neither socially nor economically optimal originates in three observations, namely that (i) imperfections in markets for credit and insurance will affect decisions on whether or not to participate in land markets, and that in particular subsistence constraints can force households to take decisions based on short term requirements that are inconsistent with maximization of welfare in the long term; (ii) differences in producers access to information will lead to variation in transaction costs; and (iii) land may be acquired for speculative purposes unrelated to its use in agricultural production. Households decision problem can be illustrated by considering the option of holding two assets, one, e.g. land, with high returns but that is also risky and illiquid, and another one, e.g. grain, with lower returns but less risk and higher liquidity. At every point in time, households choose a combination between these two assets to maximize utility over the entire lifetime and subject to limits for borrowing and an overall budget constraint. While an analytical solution to this problem is impossible unless more structure is imposed, numerical simulations show that credit market imperfections and risk, households need to satisfy basic subsistence needs can give rise to land being supplied to the market by producers who are forced to sell under duress in bad years, often to individuals with access to non-covariate income streams outside the local rural economy or large amounts of assets (Zimmerman and Carter 1999). In high-risk environments this may lead the poor to rationally prefer assets with a lower but more stable return to land even if transaction costs were modest and they had access to credit to acquire it. With imperfect credit markets, some households will be able to buy and accumulate land not because they would be more productive but due to their ability to better overcome such market imperfections (Carter and Salgado 2001, Zimmerman and Carter 2003). Similarly, others may be forced to sell use land markets to sell land in exchange for less risky assets to minimize their exposure to risk even though they would be able to make more productive use of the land than those who acquire it (Rosenzweig and Binswanger 1993). In addition to these factors, macroeconomic instability, expectations of future land price hikes, lack of sufficiently attractive alternative assets, policies, and the valuation of land for non-productive reasons, all will affect households participation in land sales markets independently from their innate productivity. We model these two sets of factors that will affect land markets in a rather independent manner in our 12

ordered probit estimation as discussed below. A direct consequence of this is that the productivity- and equity impact of land sales market operation will depend on the extent to which other markets function and net effects of land sales markets are ambiguous a priori and will have to be decided empirically depending on whether or not risk is high.. As India inherited a highly unequal distribution of land from its colonial masters, it is not surprising that land reform was at the center of policy discussions for a long time. In this environment where other factor markets were highly imperfect, distress sales had historically played a major role (Kranton and Swamy 1999). Evidence suggests that households access to insurance substitutes allowing them to buffer consumption during crisis had a significant impact on whether land sales markets helped to equalize endowments or contributed to further dis-equalization (Cain 1981). To halt these tendencies, virtually all states implemented, during the 1960s and 70s, different types of land reform measures, mainly in the form of land ceilings and security against eviction as well as rent ceilings for tenants. 11 In addition to these, legislation in virtually all states prohibits land transfers from tribals to non-tribals. Transaction cost are further increased by stamp duty which has to be paid upon registration of a sale and which in most cases amounts to more than 10% of land value (Alm et al. 2004). Based on the above, we explore three issues, namely (i) whether land sales promote efficiency of land use by transferring it to households with higher levels of ability; (ii) the extent to which land sales contribute to equalization of endowments, i.e. transfer land from labor-poor and land-rich to labor-rich and landpoor households; and (iii) whether shocks and policies affect the outcomes observed in land sales markets. Further, we are interested to see how land sales compare to non-market transfers. We distinguish factors that affect households or dynasties latent demand for land due to their level of productivity from other factors, unrelated to productivity, that may prevent them from exercising this demand or force them to sell even if doing so runs counter to long-term maximization of productivity using an ordered probit model with variable upper and lower thresholds for land market participation. Latent demand is determined by their current and expected future ability to make productive use of the land. Actual participation decisions will, in addition, be affected by factors unrelated to productivity such as transaction costs and shocks. Formally, we assume that latent demand for land depends on long-term productivity which can be expressed as a reduced form equation f(α, A,L,K,O)= β 0 + β 1 α + β 2 A + β 3 K + β 4 L+ β 5 N (3) 11 Ceilings on the amount of land that could be held by an individual or household although implementation effort varied widely and generally was much delayed until the early 1970s. Contrary to Korea, where land owners anticipation of such ceilings led to a tremendous increase in land sales market transactions that transferred income to former tenants and increased productivity (Jeon and Kim 2000), they were largely evaded by spurious subdivisions (Kaushik 2005). Where, as in West Bengal, implementation of land reform legislation was effective, ceilings are still credited with having led to greater land sales market activity (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2006). 13

Thresholds for the transition between sales and autarky and autarky and purchase are defined as follows: p S (T) = η 0 +η 1 S+η 2 C+η 3 G+η 4 (C S)+ η 5 (G S)+ η 6 Z (4) p B (T) = δ 0 +δ 1 S+ δ 2 C+δ 3 G+ δ 4 (C S)+ δ 5 (G S)+ δ 6 Z (5) where S denotes whether or not the household experienced a weather shock, defined as a level of rain below the average for two consecutive growing seasons, C denotes credit access, G local availability of mechanisms for risk coping, in particular the employment guarantee scheme, Z is a vector of other characteristics, and the βs, δs andηs are parameters to be estimated. Factors affecting the extent of participation in the main equation are the level of ability and the dynasty s endowment with land, labor, and assets, the length of the households independent existence in 1999 and the position in the life cycle which are represented empirically by a dummy for whether a household is from a landless dynasty and the dynasty s land endowment to represent A and initial asset endowments and levels of per capita consumption to proxy for K. To proxy for lifecycle events and concerns about inter-generational transmission, the number of unmarried sons aged between 5 and 25 years in 1981. We expect β 1 > 0 and β 2 < 0 as high levels of agricultural ability increase producers marginal product and thus their competitiveness in land markets while standard assumptions for the production function imply a negative relationship between land endowment and marginal product. In other words, higher agricultural ability or lower land endowment will increase a household s likely propensity to shift from autarkic to land purchase and less likely to move away from autarkic to land sale. As, with imperfections in credit and labor markets, higher levels of wealth or family labor will increase a household s marginal productivity, we expectβ 3 >0, β 4 >0, and β 5 >0. Concerning the variables in the threshold equations, note that Z includes policy constraints on tribals land market participation, the inequality of land holdings in the village that will affect transaction costs in the land market, and the growth rate of village income to proxy for non-farm opportunities. We expect negative weather shocks to increase the supply of land to the market through (distress) sales and safety nets to reduce it as they improve poor people s ability to cope with unanticipated shocks, thus η 1 >0, and η 3 <0. While presence of banks also improves the ability to cope with shocks, it will also provide greater liquidity that would increase land market activity, making the sign of η 2 indeterminate. As safety nets and banks improve the ability to cope with shocks, we expect η 4 <0 and η 5 <0. On the supply side, we expect shocks (village employment schemes) to increase (decrease) land supply to the market, hence δ 1 <0, and δ 3 >0. By the same liquidity argument as above we expect that δ 3 <0. If access to banks and safety nets reduces the supply of land to markets through distress sales and less supply would reduce the number of those being able to buy land, we expect δ 4 >0 and δ 5 >0. Finally, the 14

presence of constraints on market participation by tribals leads us to expect a negative (positive) sign on the coefficient for ST/SCs in the upper (lower) threshold equation. On the other hand, by increasing the scope for productivity-enhancing land transactions, economic growth at the village level is expected to increase land market activity, thus we expect the coefficient on this variable to be positive (negative) in the upper and lower threshold equations, respectively. To compare effects of market transactions to those of non-market transactions (i.e., inheritance, gift, dowry, etc), we run an ordered probit model that identifies key determinants for non-market land transfers with some modifications of the variables to be included in the ordered probit model. For example, the entire argument of transaction costs associated with land sale and land purchase will not be relevant to inheritance and gift exchange. Correspondingly, we treat the two thresholds in the ordered probit model as constant. As discussed earlier in the estimation strategy section, we treated the lower and upper bounds of the ordered probit model as constant because the transaction costs are unlikely to be relevant to nonmarket transactions. 3.3 Descriptive statistics The share of households who, in 1982-1999, obtained or transferred land through market (i.e. sale and purchase) compared to non-market (i.e. inheritance) mechanisms, is presented in table 2. With 15% and 8% (or 0.88% and 0.47% annually) of the population and 9% and 5% of the land involved in purchasing or selling land, respectively, the level of land sales market activity in the data is in line with what has been reported by other Indian studies (Mani and Gandhi 1994, Dreze et al. 1997, Rawal 2001). 12 It is of interest to note significant regional differences, with land purchase markets being quite inactive in the North (6% of population and 3% of land) but relatively active in the South (25% and 18% of population and land). Access to land through non-market channels is, with 10% in terms of households (or 7% in terms of land), less frequent than access through markets, and overlap between the two minimal. Also, even in the most active areas, land sales and purchase markets are much less active than those for rental in which 15% and 9% participated in 1999 alone (Deininger et al. 2006). As attrition was carefully controlled for, and most household splits were actually traced, the fact that the share of those reporting to have purchased land during the period is higher than that of those who sold is most likely due to the fact that sellers sold land in small plots to more than one buyer. Moving from aggregate to household-level information, table 3 describes initial and final characteristics for the whole sample and by households participation in market transactions (i.e., selling, buying, and 12 Rawal (2001) reports a number of studies from India that find that in most cases the share of land transacted annually was below 0.5%. Part of the reason for this low figure may be the fact that in the studies quoted, the denominator was total village land rather than the land owned by survey respondents. 15

remaining in autarky, in columns 2, 3 and 4) and non-market transfers (i.e., inherited out and autarky in columns 6 and 5) during the period under concern. 13 The top panel provides information on initial conditions in 1982 while the bottom panel illustrates the status in 1999. We first discuss information for market-participants followed by that for groups according to their non-market participation. 14 Initial conditions for market participants allow three main conclusions. First, data point towards strong equalization of factor endowments through land sales; households who sold land had significantly smaller initial adult populations and per capita landholdings than purchasers (3.8 vs. 4.4 persons in the 14-60 age group and 2 vs. 1.3 ha per capita, respectively) and 15% of those purchasing land came from a landless dynasty. 15 At the same time, there were no significant difference in initial non-land asset endowments or the level of per capita income between those who purchased and sold land and those remaining in autarky although the two former groups had slightly higher initial consumption levels than the latter. Second, the fact that the number of unmarried sons and daughters for sellers (1.08 and 0.78) and buyers (0.88 and 0.68) is markedly above that of those in autarky (0.73 and 0.51) points towards a link between land market participation and live cycle events. Finally, with 9% and 13% in sales and purchase markets, compared to 17% overall, land market participation by scheduled caste households was uniformly low. Shifting from initial to final conditions in the bottom panel of table 3 provides a number of insights. First, while differences in household size persisted in 1999, those who purchased land had made welfare gains that were more than 50% above those for the rest. Compared to initial levels that were not different from those by the rest or even slightly below average, purchasers levels of final asset ownership (Rs. 86,748 vs. about 57,000 for the rest of the sample), per capita income (Rs. 4,063 vs. 2,500), and expenditure (1,908 vs. 1,579 and 1,724), were all significantly above non-participants and sellers in 1999. This was accompanied by purchasers shifting from the bottom of the three groups in terms of per capita land endowment to the top, with a significantly higher end-period level of 1.12 as compared to 0.7 ha per capita, for the rest of the sample. The extent to which such performance was underpinned by higher levels of productivity will have to be explored in the econometric analysis. Although 29% of sellers in the sample became landless, their asset and income levels in 1999 were not significantly different from those in the autarky group with their per capita income significantly above the latter. Even though some sales 13 Columns 2-4 identify changes in welfare over time between those who sold and purchased while columns 5 and 6 point towards generational differences between the old and the young generation for households who transferred land through inheritance and those who did not. In both cases, the results of t-tests for the significance of differences between the group transferring land and those remaining in autarky are indicated by stars as explained in the table. 14 The discrepancy of number of observations between 1982 and 1999 (5932 versus 3816) is due to household splits in the 1982-99 period. Of the 3816 households of the initial sample that could be traced in the second round, 1174 split and formed a total of 3290 new households while 2642 did not experience any change, bringing the total number to 5933. 15 In other words, more than 60% of those who had been landless at the start of the period were able to acquire land through the market. At the same time 2% of the sample who were landless in 1982 managed to acquire land but had sold it by the end of the period. 16