Housing Collateral and Entrepreneurship

Similar documents
Housing Collateral and Entrepreneurship

Housing Collateral and Entrepreneurship

Housing Collateral and Entrepreneurship

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

Do Family Wealth Shocks Affect Fertility Choices?

Real Estate Boom and Misallocation of Capital in China

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount?

House Price Shock and Changes in Inequality across Cities

Sorting based on amenities and income

The Effects of Land Title Registration on Tenure Security, Investment and Production

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1

ONLINE APPENDIX "Foreclosures, House Prices, and the Real Economy" Atif Mian Amir Sufi Francesco Trebbi [NOT FOR PUBLICATION]

Identifying the Benefits from Home Ownership: A Swedish Experiment

House Prices, Household Leverage, and Entrepreneurship

Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

Aggregation Bias and the Repeat Sales Price Index

House Prices and Economic Growth

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers?

Young-Adult Housing Demand Continues to Slide, But Young Homeowners Experience Vastly Improved Affordability

Negative Gearing and Welfare: A Quantitative Study of the Australian Housing Market

Over the past several years, home value estimates have been an issue of

Housing market and finance

Using Hedonics to Create Land and Structure Price Indexes for the Ottawa Condominium Market

DEMAND FR HOUSING IN PROVINCE OF SINDH (PAKISTAN)

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Real Estate Booms and Endogenous Productivity Growth

THE TAXPAYER RELIEF ACT OF 1997 AND HOMEOWNERSHIP: IS SMALLER NOW BETTER?

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

The Impact of Internal Displacement Inflows in Colombian Host Communities: Housing

A Quantitative Approach to Gentrification: Determinants of Gentrification in U.S. Cities,

Macro-prudential Policy in an Agent-Based Model of the UK Housing Market

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

MEASURING THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATE ON HOUSING DEMAND

Susanne E. Cannon Department of Real Estate DePaul University. Rebel A. Cole Departments of Finance and Real Estate DePaul University

Online Appendix "The Housing Market(s) of San Diego"

The Housing Price Bubble, Monetary Policy, and the Foreclosure Crisis in the U.S.

Volume 35, Issue 1. Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal

Technical Description of the Freddie Mac House Price Index

Housing Price Forecasts. Illinois and Chicago PMSA, December 2015

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Modelling a hedonic index for commercial properties in Berlin

Consumption of Housing During the 2000s Boom: Evidence and Theory

Technical Line SEC staff guidance

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

The Effects of Local Risk on Homeownership *

Linkages Between Chinese and Indian Economies and American Real Estate Markets

86 years in the making Caspar G Haas 1922 Sales Prices as a Basis for Estimating Farmland Value

A STUDY OF THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA S APARTMENT RENTAL MARKET 2000 TO 2015: THE ROLE OF MILLENNIALS

Housing Transfer Taxes and Household Mobility: Distortion on the Housing or Labour Market? Christian Hilber and Teemu Lyytikäinen

Homeowner Balance Sheets and Monetary Policy

Analysis on Natural Vacancy Rate for Rental Apartment in Tokyo s 23 Wards Excluding the Bias from Newly Constructed Units using TAS Vacancy Index

Gender Differences in Negotiation: Evidence from Real Estate Transactions

An Examination of Potential Changes in Ratio Measurements Historical Cost versus Fair Value Measurement in Valuing Tangible Operational Assets

REDSTONE. Regression Fundamentals.

Foreclosures, House Prices, and the Real Economy*

The Uneven Housing Recovery

An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria through the Lens of Fundamentals

Housing Wealth in Austria

Foreclosures, House Prices, and the Real Economy*

Foreclosures, House Prices, and the Real Economy

Gregory W. Huffman. Working Paper No. 01-W22. September 2001 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235

The Impact of Urban Growth on Affordable Housing:

Description of IHS Hedonic Data Set and Model Developed for PUMA Area Price Index

A Comparison of Downtown and Suburban Office Markets. Nikhil Patel. B.S. Finance & Management Information Systems, 1999 University of Arizona

Myth Busting: The Truth About Multifamily Renters

The impact of parking policy on house prices

Land-Use Regulation in India and China

Messung der Preise Schwerin, 16 June 2015 Page 1

Effects of Zoning on Residential Option Value. Jonathan C. Young RESEARCH PAPER

A Brief Overview of H-GAC s Regional Growth Forecast Methodology

DATA APPENDIX. 1. Census Variables

Appreciation Rates of Land Values

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore

Quantifying the relative importance of crime rate on Housing prices

Why did financial institutions sell RMBS at fire sale prices during the financial crisis?

Neighborhood Externalities and Housing Price Dynamics

Regional Housing Trends

Consumption of Housing During the 2000s Boom: Evidence and Theory

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Real Estate Boom and Misallocation of Capital in China *

The Effects of Securitization, Foreclosure, and Hotel Characteristics on Distressed Hotel Prices, Resolution Time, and Recovery Rate

While the United States experienced its larg

Objectives of Housing Task Force: Some Background

acuitas, inc. s survey of fair value audit deficiencies August 31, 2014 pcaob inspections methodology description of a deficiency

The Speculation and Crowding Out Channel: Real Estate Shocks and Corporate Investment in China

Estimating the Value of the Historical Designation Externality

The survey also examines the underlying causes of FVM and impairment audit

Waiting for Affordable Housing in NYC

Housing Price Forecasts. Illinois and Chicago PMSA, April 2018

Economic and monetary developments

On the Responsiveness of Housing Development to Rent and Price Changes: Evidence from Switzerland

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

Outshine to Outbid: Weather-Induced Sentiments on Housing Market

Transcription:

Housing Collateral and Entrepreneurship Martin C. Schmalz, David A. Sraer, and David Thesmar September 10, 2013 Abstract This paper shows that collateral constraints restrict entrepreneurial activity. Our empirical strategy uses variations in local house prices as shocks to the value of collateral available to individuals owning a house and control for local demand shocks by comparing entrepreneurial activity by homeowners and renters operating in the same region. We find that an increase in collateral value leads to a higher probability of becoming an entrepreneur. Conditional on entry, entrepreneurs with access to more valuable collateral create larger firms, more value added and are more likely to survive in the long run. Schmalz: Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, schmalz@umich.edu; Sraer: Princeton University, NBER and CEPR, dsraer@princeton.edu; Thesmar: HEC Paris and CEPR, thesmar@hec.fr. For helpful comments and discussions we would like to thank Sugato Bhattacharyya, Markus Brunnermeier, Denis Gromb, Antoinette Schoar, José Scheinkman, as well as seminar participants at the University of Michigan and the University of Amsterdam. All errors are our own.

1. Introduction This paper provides evidence that entrepreneurs face credit constraints, which restrict firm creation, post-entry growth, and survival, even over the long run. The existing literature documents a strong correlation between entrepreneurial wealth and the propensity to start or keep a business (Evans and Jovanovic, 1989; Evans and Leighton, 1989; Holtz-Eakin et al., 1993). There is, however, a considerable debate about whether such a correlation is evidence of financial constraints. For instance, individuals who experience a wealth shock, e.g., through personal accumulation or inheritance, may have more business opportunities for reasons unrelated to their wealth (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004). Policies aimed at facilitating the financing of new businesses would then be of no positive value to society. Worse yet, in the absence of financial constraints, positive shocks to entrepreneurial wealth may lead to excessive investment, provided that entrepreneurs derive private benefits from remaining in business (Andersen and Nielsen, 2011; Nanda, 2011). On the other hand, if financing frictions lead to underinvestment and fewer than optimal business starts, public intervention in favor of small firm financing may be welfare improving. For these reasons, the question of whether financing constraints significantly hinder firm creation and growth carries large policy implications. To contribute to this debate, this paper uses variations in local house prices, combined with micro-level data on home ownership by entrepreneurs. We employ a difference-indifferences approach. We compare entrepreneurial outcomes of entrepreneurs owning a house and entrepreneurs renting a house, and compare this difference across geographic regions with different dynamics of house prices. The comparison between owners and non-owners allows us to filter out local economic shocks that may drive the creation, growth, and survival of businesses. Next, the relative comparison of owners versus renters across regions allows for the identification of a collateral channel in entrepreneurship, as in (Chaney et al., 2012) for the case of capital expenditures of publicly traded corporations. We adapt this methodology to investigate both the extensive and intensive margin of 1

entrepreneurship, i.e. entry decisions as well as post-entry growth. Our investigation starts with firm growth and survival, conditional on entry. We construct a large cross-section of French entrepreneurs starting a businesses in 1998. Combining survey data and administrative data, we are able to observe a variety of personal characteristics, in particular the home location of the entrepreneurs, as well as their home ownership status. We match this information to firm-level accounting data of the newly created firms for up to 8 years following creation. We find that in regions with larger house price growth in the 1990s, firms started by homeowners are significantly larger and more likely to survive than firms started by renters. This effect is robust to controlling for a large set of entrepreneurial characteristics. It is also quite persistent: in 2005, firms started by entrepreneurs with lower collateral values in 1998 remain significantly smaller in terms of assets, sales, employment or value added. Finally, this effect is economically large: going from the 25th to the 75th percentile of house price growth in the 5 years preceding creation allows homeowners to create firms that are 6.5% larger in terms of total assets. We then investigate how access to valuable collateral affects the probability of starting a business, i.e. the extensive margin of entrepreneurship. To this end, we use the French labor force survey (LFS), which is a rotating panel that tracks randomly selected individuals for three consecutive years. Importantly, the French LFS contains information on home ownership, geographic location, and entrepreneurial activity. We find that homeowners in regions where house prices appreciate more are significantly more likely to create businesses, relative to renters located in the same regions. In other words, the difference in the propensity to start a business between owners and renters is larger in regions in which house prices appreciated more in the past. Again, the effects are economically sizable. Going from the 25th to the 75th percentile of past house price growth increases the probability of firm creation by homeowners, relative to renters, by 7-13% depending on the specification. We confirm the importance of this result in the aggregate: total firm creation at the regional level is more correlated with house prices in regions where the fraction of homeowners is 2

larger. This paper contributes to the literature on financing constraints and entrepreneurship. The extant literature focuses on the link between entrepreneurial wealth and firm creation, growth or survival. Hurst and Lusardi (2004) and Adelino et al. (2013) are closest to our paper, as they also investigate the role of housing wealth on firm creation. However, our paper makes two significant advances relative to these contributions: (1) the information on individual homeownership allows us to control for local economic shocks that might create a spurious correlation between entrepreneurial rate and local house prices, and (2) the nature of our data allows us to track not only firm creation at the individual level, but also post entry growth and survival over a long horizon. Several earlier papers focus on the role of inheritance shocks to firm quality and survival. Holtz-Eakin et al. (1993) find that firms started after a large inheritance are more likely to survive, a finding they interpret as evidence of credit constraints. In contrast, using Danish data, Andersen and Nielsen (2011) find that businesses started following a large inheritance have lower performance. This suggests that the relationship between wealth and entrepreneurship may be driven by private benefits of control, or in other words that business ownership has a luxury good component (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004). The relation between wealth shocks and post-entry growth/survival is thus still largely an open discussion. Our paper contributes to this debate by looking at wealth shocks triggered by local variations in house prices for homeowners. Additionally, the size of inheritance received by entrepreneurs could well be related to business opportunities, e.g., through family connections. By relying on local variations in house prices and the difference between owners and renters, we believe that our paper improves on the identification of the effect of wealth shocks on entrepreneurship. Fracassi et al. (2012) also provide a clean identification on the role that credit constraints play on small business survival by exploiting a discontinuity in the attribution of loans to start-ups at a small local bank. While this paper focuses on credit supply, our paper focuses on credit demand. 3

Our paper also contributes to the emerging literature on the link between economic activity and collateral values (Black et al., 1996; Bernanke and Gertler, 1986; Kiyotaki and Moore, 1995), particularly real estate collateral. When house prices increase, firms and households have more collateral to pledge, which raises borrowing capacity. On the credit supply size banks balance sheets become stronger, which allows them to lend more. Recent papers have documented the link between house prices and household borrowing and consumption (Mian et al., 2011; Gan, 2010), the link between real estate prices and corporate investment (Gan, 2007a; Chaney et al., 2012) and the link between real estate bubbles and bank lending (Gan, 2007b). Our paper shows that entrepreneurial activity also strongly reacts to changes in the value of collateral available to potential entrepreneurs. The paper has four remaining sections. Section 2 describes the data we use. Section 3 lays out the empirical strategy. We describe and comment on the results in Section 4. Section 5 concludes. 2. Data The paper uses two different datasets. The first is a random sample of one sixth of all entrepreneurs starting a firm in France in 1998, with detailed information on both the entrepreneur herself and the firm she creates. We use this sample to investigate the impact of housing wealth on post-entry growth and survival. We call this dataset the intensive margin sample. The second dataset is a representative 3-year rotating panel of French individuals, covering the 1990-2002 period, with detailed information on occupation and personal characteristics. This sample is used to investigate how the propensity to start a business is affected by shocks to housing wealth. We call this dataset the extensive margin sample. 4

2.1. Intensive Margin Sample This first dataset is constructed from the 1998 wave of the SINE survey (see Landier and Thesmar (2009) for a thorough description of this data source). This survey is run by the French statistical office every four years. It selects a random sample of approximately one third of all firms started in France during the first semester. Questionnaires are sent out to the selected firms, and due to its administrative nature, the survey response rate is high (85%). The survey contains detailed information on the entrepreneur (age, education, work experience, etc.) and her project (ambition, industry, scope, form of business, etc.). Importantly for our purpose, the survey asks the entrepreneur whether she owns or rents her private home. To measure post entry growth, we use accounting information from the tax files from the Finance Ministry. These files, available yearly from 1999 to 2005, cover all firms that are subject to either the regular corporate tax regime (Bénéfice Réel Normal) or to the simplified corporate tax regime (Régime Simplifié d Imposition). Together represent about 55% of newly created firms. Small firms with annual sales below 32,600 Euros (81,500 Euros in retail and wholesale trade) can opt out and choose a special micro-business tax regime (Micro-Entreprise), in which case they do not appear in the tax files. The tax files contain firms entire balance sheet. In particular, they contain information on location, total assets, total sales, financial debt, number of employees, value added and the wage bill and they are available yearly up to 2007. As in the SINE survey, each firm in the tax file is uniquely identified by its SIREN number. We hand-collect information on house prices from the office of French notaries. This data is available at the level of the région from 1985 to 1997 and at the level of the département between 1990 and 2002. There are 95 départements in France, which form 27 régions. A département is roughly equivalent in size to an MSA in the US. We use the finest level of granularity available for each regression. There are a total of 21,871 entrepreneurs surveyed in the 1998 wave of the SINE survey. 5

Of them, 17,120 have information on the entrepreneur s home ownership status, 10,186 of them have non-missing information on total assets in the tax files, and 8,869 of them have information on all the control variables we use in our main specification (occupation previous to starting the firm, age, education, gender, business form, industry and firm location). Table 1 presents summary statistics of the intensive margin dataset. Panel A reports the distribution of the house price indices across geographic regions. Over the 1992 to 1997 period, real estate prices grew by 3% on average (median of 3% as well). Importantly for our identification strategy, this average number conceals a substantial heterogeneity of house price growth across regions in this time period. The standard deviation of house price growth from 1992 to 1997 is 10%. Out of the 21 regions in France, two experienced house price declines in that period. In particular, Ile-de-France, the region containing Paris, experienced a severe decline of house prices by more than 20%. This house price crash will be part of our identification strategy detailed in Section 3. Panel B reports the firm characteristics we use as controls in our regression analysis for the first whole fiscal year after creation, i.e., in 1999. The average firm has AC166k in assets, AC240k in sales, AC127k debt, close to two employees, and creates a value of AC206k, of which AC53k are wages, and AC153k is value added (revenue less outside purchases of materials and services). As expected, all these variables have positive skewness: In the median firm, the owner is the only firm s employee. Table 7 compares characteristics of owners and renters. Notably, home owners run smaller businesses that create less value, and are less educated than renters. In sum, the unconditional comparison of owners and renters rejects the notion that homeowners unconditionally are richer, more educated, or otherwise more able to run a business. Panel C describes the personal characteristics of the entrepreneurs in our sample. 28% of these entrepreneurs are homeowners. 42% of the businesses they create take the legal form of a sole proprietorship (as opposed mostly to limited liability corporations). 41% of these businesses are operated directly from the entrepreneurs private home. The average 6

entrepreneur is 37 years old. 78% are male. Only 23% of the entrepreneurs in our sample have a university degree, but 40% have professional training comparable to an associate s degree in the United States. Most of the firms (53%) are created by founders who were employed immediately before starting their business, but a substantial fraction start businesses while unemployment (37%) or from out of the workforce (11%). Figure 1 gives the industry distribution. Construction, retail, and consulting, are the most common industries in which new businesses get started. 2.2. Extensive Margin Sample Our second dataset uses the yearly waves of the French Labor Force Survey from 1990 to 2002. The French LFS ( Enquête Emploi ) is a 3-year rotating panel, which is in many ways similar to the US PSID. The unit of observation is the home address, so that the survey misses out on households who move. But conditionally on staying in the same home, this survey allows us to observe transitions from being dependently employed to entrepreneurship/self employment during the three years in which an individual is surveyed. Importantly for our purpose, the French LFS also contains information on home ownership, as well as on the geographic location of the respondent. We drop retirees and students from the original sample, as well as individuals under 20 or older than 64. We only keep individuals that are not entrepreneurs/self-employed in year 2. For each individual in this selected sample, we then create a dummy equal to 1 if the individual starts-up a business in year 3. Table 2, panel B, presents summary statistics for this sample. On average, 1.3% of wage earner in year 2 become self-employed in year 3 of the survey. 57% of individuals surveyed own their house and 6% are unemployed. The median respondent is 43 years old. 15% of respondents are women, 6% are foreigners. Finally, 37% of the respondents have no diploma, while 10% have a college degree. 1 We then merge this 1 Table 8 compares characteristics of owners and renters. While new entrepreneurs who own a house are less educated and have smaller businesses, in the general population, wealth and education is correlated with home ownership. 7

dataset with the sample of regional house prices described in the previous section. Dataset for Region-level Regressions As a complement to our extensive margin results, we run aggregate regressions at the département level. We compute the fraction of homeowners in 1990 using the (exhaustive) 1990 census. It is defined as the fraction of first houses (as opposed to secondary houses) in the département that are owned by their occupant. We measure firm creation at the département level by aggregating information from the Business Creation Registry maintained by the French statistical office (INSEE). This dataset contains the universe of firms created in France with their precise date, location, legal form (limited liability corporation or sole proprietorship) and employment at birth. We also obtain information from INSEE on the industry composition of the workforce, by département. Table 2, panel C, presents summary statistics for this sample. 3. Empirical Strategy We perform three sets of empirical analyses. The first focuses on the intensive margin of entrepreneurship, i.e., post-entry growth of newly created businesses conditional on entry, at the individual level. The second focuses on the extensive margin of entrepreneurship, i.e., the probability of entry into entrepreneurship at the individual level. The third focuses on the extensive margin of entrepreneurship, but at the aggregate (regional) level. 3.1. Intensive Margin Regressions Our research question in this Section is how, conditional on entry, access to valuable collateral affects the size of newly created firms. To this end, we work from the sample described in Section 2.1, which is a cross-section of entrepreneurs starting their business in the first semester of 1998. We then estimate the following specification, where i is an entrepreneur/firm and j 8

is the region of location of the entrepreneur: Y 1999 ij = α+β D(owner) i p 1992 1997 j +θ D(Owner) i +γ Z i +τ Z i p 1992 1997 j +δ l +ε i,j (1) The 1999 upper script denotes the fact that the outcome variable is measured in 1999, i.e. for the first whole fiscal year after creation, which happens in 1998. The outcome variables we consider are the logarithm of: total assets, total sales, total debt, number of employees, value added and total wage bill. D(owner) is a dummy equal to 1 if the entrepreneur is a homeowner. p 1992 1997 j is real estate price growth in region j from 1992 to 1997. As already described in Section 2.1, house prices varied a lot across regions in France in the 90s, delivering capital gains (or losses) to homeowners in different regions. δ l are département fixed effects. The Z i s are control variables for the business owner (occupation previous to becoming an entrepreneur, age, education, gender) or for the firm she creates (legal form of the business sole proprietorship or limited liability corporation industry, whether the business is operated from the private home of the entrepreneur or elsewhere. These controls are interacted with p 1992 1997 j. We cluster error terms at the region level. Similar results obtain when clustering at the départment level. Equation 1 can be interpreted as a difference-in-difference strategy. The first difference can be thought of as a comparison between the size of new businesses created by homeowners in regions with high house price growth from 1993 to 1998 and regions with low house price growth from 1993 to 1998. Intuitively, if entrepreneurs need real estate collateral in order to access external financing, homeowners should be able to create larger firms in regions that recently experienced large real estate inflation relative to regions where real estate prices have recently gone down. However, a booming real estate market might be a market with better investment opportunities, which could also explain why homeowners create larger firms in those regions. If this is the case though, i.e. past house price appreciation is just a proxy for 9

investment opportunities, then renters should also be creating larger firms in those regions with recent house price appreciation. Renters can thus be seen as a control group a group of entrepreneurs who are not exposed to variations in collateral values (the treatment) but who are exposed to similar local investment opportunities as homeowners (the treated group). Our identification strategy thus consists in investigating whether in regions where homeowners experienced large capital gains from 1992 to 1997, the size of firms created by homeowners, benchmarked on the size of firms created by renters in the same region, is larger than in regions where homeowners experienced smaller capital gains (or even losses). A positive β coefficient our coefficient of interest in equation 1 would indicate this is the case. The null hypothesis that collateral values are irrelevant for entrepreneurial activity would lead to β = 0. Equation 1 is thus identified using the interaction of two main sources of variation in the data: homeownership by entrepreneurs and region-level variations in house prices in the 1990 s. The comparison between renters and homeowners is the key difference between our approach and what people have traditionally done in the literature (Hurst and Lusardi (2004) and Adelino et al. (2013)). Our approach relies on the following identifying assumption: the size gap between firms created by homeowners and renters is independent of the local housing market, except for the role played by collateral. In other words, if there were no financing frictions, the difference in the size of businesses created by renters and borrowers should be constant across regions. This is of course a strong assumption, as there might be entrepreneurial characteristics that correlate both with the propensity to own a house and with the sensitivity of investment opportunities to the local market. For instance, older entrepreneurs are less likely to own their house and may be more likely to start business in industries that have a greater exposure to local economic activity, e.g., in retail. This would invalidate our identifying assumption and introduce an upward bias in the estimation of β. While we can t test our assumption, we try to alleviate this concern by controlling in Equation 1 for a variety of 10

personal/firm characteristics that might be correlated with the own vs. rent decision and might also be correlated with the sensitivity of investment opportunities to the local market. The characteristics we control for are variables for the business owner (occupation previous to becoming an entrepreneur, age, education, gender) or for the firm she creates (legal form of the business sole proprietorship or limited liability corporation industry, whether the business is operated from the private home of the entrepreneur or elsewhere). By interacting these variables with our price growth variable in equation 1, we make sure that our effect is not driven by composition effects arising from renters having different observable characteristics than homeowners. In other words, once we include these interaction effects, our identifying assumption becomes that the unobservable heterogeneity in the rent vs. own decision of individuals is not correlated with how the individual s investment opportunities depend on local economic activity. This is clearly a weaker assumption. However, as in (Chaney et al., 2012), we do not have a valid instrument for the decision to own or rent and this is a shortcoming of our approach. We also investigate how access to valuable collateral affects entrepreneurial outcome in the long run. To this end, we estimate equation 1, but replace the outcome variables measured in 1999 with the same outcome variables measured in later years (up to 2005). We separately examine the role of financing constraints on survival, by using a survival dummy for various horizons (2, 3, 4 and 5 years) as a dependent variable in equation 1. 3.2. Extensive Margin Regressions Our research question in this Section is how access to valuable collateral affects the decision to become an entrepreneur. To this end, we work from the sample described in Section 2.2, which is a rotating panel of individuals who were not entrepreneurs in the previous year. This sample covers the 1990-2002 period. We then estimate the following specification, where i is an individual, j is the region of location of this individual and t is the year that corresponds 11

to the 3rd (last) year of observation in the 3-year rotating panel: Pr[E i,j,t = 1 E i,j,t 1 = 0] = α + β D(owner) i p t 6 t 1 j + θ D(Owner) i +γ Z i + τ Z i p t 6 t 1 j + δ l + ε i,j (2) where E i,j,t is a dummy variable equal to 1 if individual i living in département j is an entrepreneur at date t. As before, β is the coefficient of interest. Note that house price growth is now indexed with time t, since the dataset we employ is a panel in this regression. Controls Z i are now: education dummies, gender, foreign/national dummy, past-year wage (or UI benefit if unemployed), a dummy for past year work status (employed vs. unemployed), and age. As before, standard errors are clustered at the regional level. Equation 2 is estimated using a Probit model, but we check the robustness of the results using a linear probability model. The interpretation of equation 2 is similar to the interpretation of equation 1. Within a given region and in a given year, we compare the propensity to start a business by homeowners vs. renters. We then compare how this relative propensity varies with the capital gains enjoyed by homeowners by using both time-series variations in house prices (do we see that homeowners become more likely to become entrepreneurs relative to renters when house prices grow in the region?) and cross-section variations in house prices (do we see that homeowners become more likely to become entrepreneurs relative to renters in regions where capital gains in the past 7 years have been larger?). Our identifying assumption is also similar to the assumption underlying equation 1: for an individual in our sample, the unobserved heterogeneity in the rent vs. own decision (i.e. the part of homeownership that is not explained by our control variables Z i ) is not related to the sensitivity of its investment opportunity to the local economic activity. 12

3.3. Départment-Level Regressions In this Section, we investigate the aggregate effects of the collateral channel for entrepreneurship. To this end, we look at how regional entrepreneurial activity is affected by past appreciation of house prices in regions with high vs. low homeownership. We then estimate the following specification on our département level dataset, where j is a département and t is the year: Log(NewF irms j,t ) = α + β (%owners j,1990 ) p t 6 t 1 j + θ (%owners j,1990 ) +τ Z j,1990 p t 6 t 1 j + δ j + η t ε i,j (3) where NewF irms j,t is the number of new firms created in year t in département j. For the main regression, new firms consist only of limited liability corporations and corporations, because data on creation of sole proprietorship is available only from 1993 onward. In a robustness check, we verify that our effect holds when we consider all new firms creation starting in 1993. %owners j,1990 is the fraction of homeowners in département j in 1990. p j,(t 6) (t 1) is house price growth in the 5 years preceding year t, δ j are département fixed-effects, η t are year fixed-effects. The set of control variables we use to control for the heterogeneity in the fraction of homeowners in the département is: fraction of the working population in 1990 in the départment working in Agriculture, Manufacturing, Construction, Service and non-profit Service (measure available from the French statistical office INSEE), size of the départment measured by its population from the 1990 census, and log(median wage) in the département, obtained from the labor force survey in 1990. Error terms are clustered at the region level. Similar results obtain when clustering at the département level. In a further set of results, we use as dependent variables (i) log(employment in newly created firms) jt, again at the département level, (ii) the number of new firms created normalized 13

by the population in the départment, (iii) employment in newly created firms normalized by the population in the départment. 4. Results We present three sets of results, which provide support for the notion that the collateral channel constrains entrepreneurial activity both at the intensive and at the extensive margin, i.e., both for entry into entrepreneurship as well as for firm size at creation and in the following years. First, conditional on entrepreneurship, entrepreneurs who start after receiving large housing capital gains in the years prior to entry are able to start larger firms in terms of total assets, employment, sales, value added, and wage bill. Second, employed individuals experiencing large housing capital gains are more likely to start a business than non-homeowners or homeowners living in regions with lower house price growth. Third, in the aggregate, the elasticity of business starts to local house prices is stronger in regions with a higher ownership rate. 4.1. Intensive Margin Individual-Level Results Table 3 reports the point estimates from the estimation of equation (1). The outcome variables are log assets, log sales, log debt, log number of employees, log of value added, and log of the wage bill. The variable of interest is the interaction of the owner dummy and house price appreciation from 1992 to 1997 ( p). We control for characteristics of the business owner (occupation previous to becoming an entrepreneur, age, education, gender), legal form of the business (sole proprietorship or corporation), industry, whether the firm is located in the owners home or elsewhere, as well as all interactions of these controls with p. The regressions also include départment-fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the region level. We find significant effects of collateral values on the size of newly-created business, con- 14

ditional on business creation. Going from the 25th to the 75th percentile of house price growth from 1992 to 1997 (i.e. a 9 percentage point increase in house price growth) leads to a 6.5 percentage point (=.72.09) increase in total assets, a 5.1 percentage point (=.57.09) increase in total sales and a 2.3 percentage point (=.26.09) increase in employment. Consistent with the collateral channel, we find that this larger scale of operation following housing capital gains is accompanied with larger debt levels: going again from the 25th to the 75th percentile of house price growth leads to a 7.3 percentage point (=.81.09) increase in total debt. Table 3 also reports significant effects of collateral values on the performance of new ventures, measured by the firm s total wage bill and value added. We again find large and significant effects: going from the 25th to the 75th percentile of house price growth from 1992 to 1997 leads to a 5.8 percentage point (=.64.09) increase in value added and a 7.7 percentage points (=.85.09) increase in the firm s total wage bill. All the results in Table 3 are significant at the 1% confidence level except for the debt result, which has a p-value of.023. The effects reported in Table 3 correspond to short-term effects, in the sense that they are observed for the first whole fiscal year after creation. In Figure 2, we investigate whether access to valuable collateral has a persistent effect on firm size, sales, and the other outcome variables. To this end, we modify equation (1) by using Y t ij as the dependent variable, i.e. the outcome variables are now measured in year t [2000, 2005] and not in 1999 anymore. Importantly, home price appreciation is still measured from 1992 to 1997. Figure 2 show that most of the effect reported in Table 3 for 1999 are still observed later in the sample period. For instance, in 2005, firms created following larger housing capital gains in the 1990s still have significantly larger sales, value added and total wage bill. For all outcome variables, the effects estimated throughout the early 2000s are fairly stable and close to their 1999 value reported in Table 3. In sum, Figure 2 shows that collateral shocks have a persistent effect on the long-run behavior of newly created firms. The results in Figure 2 are conditional on survival. It could be, however, that while firms 15

with more valuable collateral at creation are still larger 5 years after creation, those firms are also less likely to survive in the long run. We thus investigate the question of collateral values and survival in Table 4. In this Table, we estimate a modified version of equation (1), where the dependent variable is the probability of bankruptcy in year t conditional on being in operation in year t-1, where t is between 2000 and 2005, and estimate this modified equation using a Probit model. 2 A negative coefficient indicates that entrepreneurs who benefit from higher housing capital gains experience lower failure hazards, i.e. a higher probability to survive. For all but one horizon, the results in Table 4 report a negative coefficient on the interaction of the ownership status and p. The one positive marginal effect in column 3 is economically small (2 percentage points) and statistically insignificant (z-stat of.8). Among the negative marginal effects, only two are statistically significant (Column 2 and 5). Column 7 of Table 4 reports the marginal effect when the dependent variable is the probability of bankruptcy before 2005 for all firms created in 1999 in our sample the overall failure hazard. The overall marginal effect is again negative (-11 percentage points) but insignificant at standard confidence level (z-stat of 1.4). Table 4 is thus inconsistent with the hypothesis that access to more valuable collateral increases the probability of failure of newly created firms. These survival results are especially important for the interpretation of the results presented in Table 3. It could be that the wealth increase consecutive to the housing capital gains experienced by homeowners makes these home owners less risk averse. As a result, they would take more risk and thus create larger, albeit riskier firms. However, this interpretation is inconsistent with the results of Table 4: if housing capital gains make entrepreneurs owning their houses less risk averse, we would expect the businesses created by these entrepreneurs to fail more frequently. Table 4 shows that this is not the case. We thus conclude that the effect of collateral values on entrepreneurial outcomes cannot be attributed to decreased risk aversion. 2 To limit the number of independent variables and avoid the incidental parameters problem, we include région fixed effects instead of r epartement fixed effects. 16

4.2. Extensive Margin Individual-Level Results The previous section discussed regressions that estimate the effect of house price appreciation on homeowners business success conditional on entry. This section looks at the entry decision itself. To this end, we use the panel extracted from the French Labor Force Survey and described in Section 2.2. In this sample, which is a three year rotating panel, the unconditional probability of becoming an entrepreneur in year 3 conditional on not being an entrepreneur in year 2 is about 1.3%. This section asks whether this probability is systematically different for homeowners who have experienced substantial housing capital gains in the past five years relative to homeowners in regions with lower house price appreciation, and compared to renters. Table 5 presents the estimation of equation (2). As explained in Section 3.2, this equation relates the probability of starting a business, conditional on not being a business owner in the previous year, to variations in local house price growth in the last five years, interacted with an individual homeownership dummy. Column 1 and 2 report marginal effects from a Probit regression. Column 3 and 4 report results from a linear probability model. Column 1 and 3 only include département- and year-fixed effects. Column 2 and 4 include additional controls (education dummies, previous year income, age, sex, a foreign nationality dummy, and as well as the interaction of these controls with local house price appreciation p). All specifications yield positive and statistically significant estimates for the interaction of house price growth and the homeownership dummy. The effects are again of a sizable magnitude. Using the point estimates from Column 4, we find that 1 s.d. increase in house price growth (.34 percentage point increase) leads to a.22 percentage point (.0065.34) increase in the probability of starting up a business. Since the unconditional probability of starting a business is 1.3%, this corresponds to a 17% increase in the probability of becoming an entrepreneur. Taken together with the results from Section 4.1, our results show that access to valuable collateral is a significant determinant of both the decision to become an entrepreneur and the size of the business created, conditional on entry. 17

We finish this section by emphasizing the importance of controlling for the homeownership status of the individual. In a seminal contribution, (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004) use data from the PSID to regress the probability of starting up a business as a function of past house price appreciation in the individual s region, without interacting the price appreciation with individual or average ownership rates. (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004) fail to find a significant and positive effect of past house price growth on the entrepreneurship decision and interpret this finding as a rejection of the hypothesis that credit constraints significantly reduce entrepreneurial activity. In Table 10, we report results that are consistent with the results in (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004), i.e. a weak, negative relationship between recent past house price appreciation in the region where the individual is located and the decision to become an entrepreneur. In addition to establishing the comparability of our sample with the PSID sample used by (Hurst and Lusardi, 2004), this Table shows how omitting to interact past house price appreciation with the homeownership status can affect the results significantly. It can be for instance that in regions with lower past house price growth, the fixed costs of entry are lower for entrepreneurs so that entry across regions is independent of past house price growth in the region. In this scenario, the collateral channel is confounded by the lower fixed costs in regions with lower house price growth. Including the interaction between p and the homeownership dummy resolves this issue to the extent that the cost of entry is similar across owners and renters across regions. Table 10 also helps rule out two additional alternative interpretations. If entrepreneurship was constrained in our sample through the bank equity channel (as is (Gan, 2007b) for capital expenditures of large corporations), then the point estimate for p in Table 10 should be positive and significant. Table?? also rules out that the effect is driven by a general positive sentiment in regions with higher house price growth. If this were the case, all entrepreneurs, independent of their homeownership status, would equally benefit from past house price appreciation. 18

4.3. Extensive Margin Region-Level Results We have shown in the previous Section that lower house price growth in a region leads to lower entrepreneurial activity by homeowners living in that region. In this section, we investigate whether these effects aggregate up at the regional level. To this end, we estimate equation (3) and show that in départements with a larger fraction of homeowners, entrepreneurial activity depends more strongly on past house price growth. Table 6 presents the results from an OLS estimation of equation (3). In this equation, local entrepreneurial activity measured either through the logarithm of the number of firms created in the département, the logarithm of employment created by new firms in the département, the number of firms created per capita in the département, or employment created by new firms in the département per capita is explained by past house price growth (from year t-6 to year t-1, where t is the year of observation) and the interaction of house price growth with the fraction of homeowners in the département. We report both unweighted (columns 1 and 3) and population-weighted (Column 2 and 4) results. Column 1 and 2 only include year and département fixed effects. Columns 3 and 4 also control for the département s industry composition, size, and median wage, as well as the interaction of these controls with past house price appreciation. All specifications yield positive and statistically significant coefficient on the interaction term. In our sample, past house price growth fosters significantly more entrepreneurial activity in départements with a large fraction of homeowners relative to départements with a lower fraction of homeowners. The magnitudes are sizable. Looking at business counts, column 3 of Panel A (the unweighted point estimate) shows that, taken at the median homeownership rate (.58%), a 1 s.d. increase in p leads to a 11.5 percent (.58.34.58) increase in the number of firms created in the département. Looking at employment, column 3 of Panel B (the unweighted point estimate) shows that for a similar variation in p, the number of jobs created in new firms in the département increase by 13.3 percent (.58.34.67). Figure 3 shows graphically the important role played by house prices on entrepreneurial 19

activity in regions with a high fraction of homeowners. This figure plots the elasticity of the département-level entrepreneurship rate to house price growth measured from t-6 to t-1 as a function of the home ownership rate in the département. For each département separately, we run a time-series regression of Log(#of new firms created) t on département-level house price growth in the last five years. These regressions are using data from 1990 to 2005, while homeownership is measured in 1990. Figure 3 is a scatter plot of these elasticities as a function of the fraction of owners in 1990 and each département in the Figure is weighted by its 1990 population size. Consistent with the regression results in Table 6, the relationship between the elasticity of business starts to past house price growth and the homeownership rate is positive. 5. Conclusions Using variations in local house prices, as well as variations in individual homeownership or the ownership rate, this paper shows that collateral frictions matter for the creation of new firms, as well as for the size of newly-created firms, both at the individual and regional level. Our paper thus highlights another channel through which house prices can affect aggregate activity. This channel is different from the one emphasized by Mian and Sufi (2012), who look at how declining house prices impair the balance sheet of levered households, contributing significantly to a decline in employment. Our analysis shows that declining house prices will also affect the supply of entrepreneurs, which may in turn deteriorate aggregate activity. Quantifying the relative importance of these two channels is an important task that we leave for further research. References Adelino, Manuel, Antoinette Schoar, and Felipe Severino, House Prices, Collateral and Self-Employment, Technical Report, Working Paper 2013. 20

Andersen, S. and K. Nielsen, Ability or Finances as Constraints to Entrepreneurship? Evidence from Survival Rates in a Natural Experiment, Evidence from Survival Rates in a Natural Experiment (June 2011), 2011. Bernanke, Ben S and Mark Gertler, Agency costs, collateral, and business fluctuations, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA 1986. Black, Jane, David De Meza, and David Jeffreys, House prices, the supply of collateral and the enterprise economy, The Economic Journal, 1996, pp. 60 75. Chaney, Thomas, David Sraer, and David Thesmar, The Collateral Channel: How Real Estate Shocks affect Corporate Investment, American Economic Review, 2012, 102 (6), 2381 2409. Evans, David S and Boyan Jovanovic, An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints, The Journal of Political Economy, 1989, pp. 808 827. and Linda S Leighton, Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship, The American Economic Review, 1989, 79 (3), 519 535. Fracassi, Cesare, Mark Garmaise, Shimon Kogan, and Gabriel Natividad, How Much Does Credit Matter for Entrepreneurial Success in the United States?, Available at SSRN 2157707, 2012. Gan, Jie, Collateral, debt capacity, and corporate investment: Evidence from a natural experiment, Journal of Financial Economics, 2007, 85 (3), 709 734., The real effects of asset market bubbles: Loan-and firm-level evidence of a lending channel, Review of Financial Studies, 2007, 20 (6), 1941 1973., Housing Wealth and Consumption Growth: Evidence From a Large Panel of Households, Review of Financial Studies, 2010, 23 (1), 2229 2267. 21

Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, David Joulfaian, and Harvey S Rosen, Sticking it out: Entrepreneurial survival and liquidity constraints, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research 1993. Hurst, E. and A. Lusardi, Liquidity constraints, household wealth, and entrepreneurship, Journal of Political Economy, 2004, 112 (2), 319 347. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and John Moore, Credit cycles, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research 1995. Landier, Augustin and David Thesmar, Financial contracting with optimistic entrepreneurs, Review of financial studies, 2009, 22 (1), 117 150. Mian, Atif, Kamalesh Rao, and Amir Sufi, Household Balance Sheets, Consumption, and the Economic Slump, Consumption, and the Economic Slump (November 17, 2011), 2011. Mian, Atif R. and Amir Sufi, What explains high unemployment? The aggregate demand channel, NBER Working Papers 17830, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc February 2012. Nanda, R., Entrepreneurship and the discipline of external finance, Technical Report 11-098, Harvard Business School Entrepreneurial Management Working Paper 2011. 22

3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 Other Healthcare Educa:on Household aid Prin:ng Pharmacies, drug stores Home improvement Automo:ve Shipbuilding, avia:on, railroad construc:on Engineering / manufacturing IT Mining Tex:le industry Wood and paper Chemical Metallurgy Electrical equipment U:li:es Construc:on Car repair Wholesale Retail Transporta:on Finance Real Estate Telecommunica:on Consul:ng Opera:ons services R&D Hotels and restaurants Recrea:on, culture, sports Figure 1: Industry distribution of newly created businesses. The graph shows the industry distribution of the businesses created in the first half of 1998 that get selected into our sample Agriculture Clothing (produc:on) Forestry 23

.5 0.5 1 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogAssets 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006.5 0.5 1 1.5 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogSales 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006.5 0.5 1 1.5 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogDebt 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006.2 0.2.4.6 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogEmployees 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 0.5 1 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogValueAdded 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006.5 0.5 1 1.5 Long run effects of D(owner) x price growth on LogWageBill 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Figure 2: Real Estate Capital Gains and Entrepreneurial Outcomes: Long-Run Effects The graphs plot coefficients and 95% confidence intervals from regressions of year-t entrepreneurial outcomes on the interaction of an ownership dummy and region-level house price growth over the 5 years prior to creating the firm (1992-1997), p. t goes from 1999 to 2005. These regressions control for characteristics of the business owner (occupation previous to becoming an entrepreneur, age, education, gender), legal form of the business (sole proprietorship or corporation), industry, whether the firm is located in the owners home or elsewhere, as well as all interactions of these controls with p. The regressions also include département fixed-effects. Standard errors are clustered at the regional level. 24

0.5 1 1.5 30 40 50 60 70 1990 ownership rate elast. of entrepreneurship rate to price growth Fitted values Figure 3: Aggregate Ownership Rate, House Price Growth and Entrepreneurial Activity. The y axis is, for each département in France, the elasticity of the entrepreneurship rate (entrepreneurs per capita) to past 5-year house price growth from 1987 to 2005. The x-axis is the home ownership rate in the département in 1990. The fitted line corresponds to the population-weighted regression at the départementlevel. 25

Table 1: Summary Statistics for the Intensive Margin Analysis. This table presents summary statistics for the sample we use in our analysis of the effect of real estate capital gains on the size at creation, conditional on starting up a company. Panel A describes house price growth from 1992-1997 across the 21 French Regions. Panel B describes the characteristics of firms created by entrepreneurs surveyed in the SINE survey in 1998 and measured in 1999 in the tax file: total assets, total sales, total debt, number of employees, value added and total wage bill. Panel C describes the characteristics of the entrepreneurs surveyed in the SINE survey in 1998: homeownership status, whether they are sole proprietors, whether they work from home, age, gender, education measured by four dummies (No Diploma, Professional Training, High School Diploma, College Diploma), Occupation previous to starting up a business (Employed, Unemployed and Out-of-the Labor Force). Mean Std. Dev. p(10) p(25) p(50) p(75) p(90) Obs. Panel A: House price growth 1992-1997 p 1997 /p 1992 1 0.03 0.10-0.03 0.00 0.03 0.09 0.13 21 Panel B: Firm characteristics (1999 book values, in thousand Euros) Asset 165.56 1,289.89 6.71 18.14 41.16 99.55 242.24 11,254 Sales 240.63 1,579.81 12.65 33.69 72.87 176.08 423.50 11,254 Debt 127.61 1,051.44 2.90 10.98 30.03 79.12 197.42 11,254 # Employees 1.94 7.14 0.00 0.00 0.00 2.00 4.00 11,254 Value Added 153.66 865.11 8.54 23.02 48.94 114.79 266.33 11,254 Total Wage 53.72 250.48 0.15 2.74 12.35 45.73 112.35 11,254 Panel C: Entrepreneur characteristics Home Owner 0.28 0.45 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 9,768 Sole Proprietor 0.42 0.49 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 11,254 Business at Home 0.41 0.49 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 11,207 Age 37.19 9.46 26.00 30.00 36.00 44.00 50.00 10,561 Gender (Male==1) 0.78 0.42 0.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 10,566 Education No Diploma 0.18 0.38 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 10,590 Professional Training 0.40 0.49 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 10,590 High School Diploma 0.19 0.39 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 10,590 College Diploma 0.23 0.42 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 10,590 Prior occupation Employed 0.53 0.50 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 10,545 Unemployed 0.37 0.48 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 10,545 Out-of-Workforce 0.11 0.31 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 10,545 26