Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 04-06

Similar documents
Policy Coordination in an Oligopolistic Housing Market

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Lecture 18 Land use externalities and the Coase theorem

Gregory W. Huffman. Working Paper No. 01-W22. September 2001 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235

Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis

Waiting for Affordable Housing in NYC

Cost Ine ciency in The Low-Income Housing Tax Credit: Evidence from Building Size

14.74 Foundations of Development Policy Spring 2009

Affordable Housing Policy. Economics 312 Martin Farnham

Incentives for Spatially Coordinated Land Conservation: A Conditional Agglomeration Bonus

Working Paper nº 16/12

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

The New Form 8-K: Interpretive Issues for REITs and REOCs

A Discrete Space Urban Model with Environmental Amenities

THE LEGAL AND FINANCIAL FRAMEWORK OF AN EFFICIENT PRIVATE RENTAL SECTOR: THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE

Economic Organization and the Lease- Ownership Decision in Water

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

Land Tenure Security and Home Maintenance: The Case of Japan

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights.

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

On the Disutility and Discounting of Imprisonment and the Theory of Deterrence

Naked Exclusion with Minimum-Share Requirements

The Impact of Rent Controls in Non-Walrasian Markets: An Agent-Based Modeling Approach

Housing. Imagine a Winnipeg...: Alternative Winnipeg Municipal Budget

Foreclosures and House Prices

Balanced ventilation in apartment buildings

Proving Depreciation

The neighbor is king: customer discrimination in the housing market

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPERTY TAXATION, ZONING, AND EFFICIENCY: A DYNAMIC ANALYSIS. Stephen Coate

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

The capitalization rate is essential to any analysis through the income

Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions

Percentage Leases and the Advantages of Regional Malls

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 4: Government intervention in the housing market: Who wins, who loses?

NEW APPROACHES TO THE THEORY OF RENTAL CONTRACTS IN AGRICULTURE. Clive Bell and Pinhas Zusman

Economic justification of non-commercial buildings renovation or substitutional construction

Mixed Tenure Communities and Neighbourhood Quality

The Economics of Commercial Real Estate Preleasing

Following is an example of an income and expense benchmark worksheet:

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY JUNE 14, 2017

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY

City and County of San Francisco

On the Relationship between Track Geometry Defects and Development of Internal Rail Defects

Sincerity Among Landlords & Tenants

Reforming housing rental market in a life-cycle model

Rents in private social housing

Housing market and finance

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

Maximization of Non-Residential Property Tax Revenue by a Local Government

Comparing Specific and Ad Valorem Taxes under Price-inelastic Demand with Quality Differentiation

Chapter 1 Economics of Net Leases and Sale-Leasebacks

Inclusive Housing Policies in Rising Markets

National Rental Affordability Scheme. Economic and Taxation Impact Study

Volume 35, Issue 1. Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal

The Corner House and Relative Property Values

Negative Gearing and Welfare: A Quantitative Study of the Australian Housing Market

Efficiency in the California Real Estate Labor Market

Refurbishment of. Apartments how do you calculate? Refurbishment costs and life expectancy. Refurbishment Costs. Life expectancy

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

On the Choice of Tax Base to Reduce. Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the Context of Electricity. Generation

Oligopoly Theory (8) Product Differentiation and Spatial Competition

Study on Compensation for Real Estate Registration Errors. Dibing Xie1, Ming Luo2

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

Rent economic rent contract rent Ricardian Theory of Rent:

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

The accounting treatment of goodwill as stipulated by IFRS 3

Intangibles CHAPTER CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to:

RoboCup Challenges. Robotics. Simulation League Small League Medium-sized League (less interest) SONY Legged League Humanoid League

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

THINGS TO CONSIDER WHEN BUYING A HOME

Public incentives and conservation easements on private land

ANZVGN 9 ASSESSING RENTAL VALUE

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

Rent Control and its Implications to the Real Estate Industry

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

Single Payments of the CAP: Where Do the Rents Go?

An Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Provision of Ecosystem Services under Climate Change

Objective/Outcome 1: Major Role of Real Estate

A NOTE ON AD VALOREM AND PER UNIT TAXATION IN AN OLIGOPOLY MODEL

2004 Cooperative Housing Journal

Rental market underdevelopment in Central Europe: Micro (Survey) I and Macro (DSGE) perspective

Distressed Properties, Vacancy Shortfall, and Entrepreneurial Incentive

New housing supply: what do we know and how can we learn more?

Joint Ownership And Its Challenges: Using Entities to Limit Liability

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

Sorting based on amenities and income

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount?

TESTING FOR COOPERATIVE BEHAVIOR: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF LAND TENURE CONTRACTS IN TEXAS

FORMALIZATION OF INFORMAL REAL ESTATE. Prof Chryssy Potsiou FIG President, UNECE WPLA bureau member

BUSI 331: Real Estate Investment Analysis and Advanced Income Appraisal

ANALYSIS OF RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MARKET VALUE OF PROPERTY AND ITS DISTANCE FROM CENTER OF CAPITAL

Land Rights and Land Reform

Solutions to Questions

There are some fundamental principles which the Council will apply when regenerating estates:

Racial Prejudice in a Search Model of the Urban Housing Market: Lewis Team Notes

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

See also Deadweight Loss; Government failure; Pricing, Ethical Issues in; Rents, Economic; Unintended Consequences, law of

Transcription:

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 4-6 Can Risk Averse Private Entrepreneurs Efficiently Produce Low Income Housing Paul Makdissi Quentin Wodon

Can Risk Averse Private Entrepreneurs E ciently Produce Low Income Housing? Paul Makdissi y Quentin Wodon z September 24 Abstract Under rent ceilings and quality oors for low income housing units, imperfect information on the ability of tenants to pay their rent may lead the decentralized production of housing units by risk averse private entrepreneurs to be ine cient. A coordinating agency and/or subsidies for new tenants would help to produce more housing, thereby increasing the pro ts for landlords while also enabling more low income households to nd housing. Keywords: Low Income Housing, Risk Aversion, Rent Control, Public Good JEL Codes: H41, R31 The opinions expressed here are those of the authors and need not represent those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. The rst author bene ted from nancial support of SSHRC and FQRSC. y Département d économique, Université de Sherbrooke, 25, boulevard de l Université, Sherbrooke, Québec, Canada, J1K 2R1; Email: paul.makdissi@usherbrooke.ca. z AFTPM, World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 2433, USA, Email: qwodon@worldbank.org. 1

1 Introduction The literature on employment points out to the fact that there is a cost for rms to match their needs with the workers that they are hiring (Jovanovic, 1979; Miller, 1984). This matching process is imperfect as rms do not have full information on the future level of productivity of the workers that they are hiring. This leads many rms to hire workers, and then re some of them (those who proved less productive) in order to hire new workers who may not appear very di erent on the basis of their observable characteristics from the workers who just lost their job. As noted by McCall (1991), the issue of matching workers with jobs is more problematic for younger workers who lack experience and have not yet proven themselves. For more experienced workers, their past successful record of employment is a signal that rms can use in order to minimize the risks associated with hiring new workers. Note that this signal on individual worker quality is available to all rms, not only to those that employed these more successful workers, since on the labor market workers make their employment record public. A similar point could be made about the housing market. New and younger tenants who have not yet proven that they are able to pay their rent (or new owners who have not yet proven that they are able to pay their mortgage) are probably more risky for landlords (or banks) than tenants or owners who have already proven themselves and have a good credit record. If markets were fully exible, the rents paid by tenants or the quality of the housing units provided to them would adjust to fully take into account these risks and the information available to landlords. But in the low income housing markets, rents are typically subject to ceilings, and housing quality must respect some minimal standards, so that costs are subjects to oors. Then there may be cases under which the decentralized provision of housing units by private landlords will not be e cient. This is because the production of information on the quality of tenants (i.e., who pays and who does not pay the rent) is a public good that will not be taken into account by private landlords in their own optimization function 1. The model presented in this paper shows that landlords may produce or make available housing units at a level at which the cost of producing new units will be below the expected bene t to them from renting these units. By contrast, a coordinating 1 A similar point was made by Makdissi and Tejedo (24) in the case of labor markets. 2

agency might better take the public good nature of the information on the quality of tenants into account, and this would result in a higher level of production and also in higher pro ts for landlords 2. In the absence of such a coordinating agency, production or other subsidies for landlords in the low income housing market would make sense on e ciency grounds apart from the more traditional equity arguments advanced in the literature 3. 2 Model and Results Consider VNM (Von Neuman-Morgenstern) private landlords maximizing their actualized expected utility of income over an in nite time horizon 4. The landlords derive their income from renting housing units in the low income housing market. market is regulated so that there is a maximum level of rent denoted by h. This production cost of housing units is given by c (q) with c () > and c () <. The landlords are risk averse, so that their preferences may be represented by a Bernoulli utility function u () with standard asumptions u and u (). The landlords face non-payment issues among their tenants, with a proportion p 2 [; 1] of non-payment among new tenants, i.e. tenants who are renting a unit for the rst time in their life. This proportion p is unknown a priori. If F () represents the cumulative distribution function of p over the interval [; 1], then its expected value is = R 1 pdf (p). Tenants live (and thereby rent their unit) for two periods. In the rst period, they rent their unit for the rst time, so that landlords do not have any speci c information on the probability that they will not pay their rent. In the second period however, the tenants have a credit rating record, so that any landlord will know if they have been good at paying their rent or not in the previous period (the fact that there is a 2 Whether the coordinating agency would itself have the incentives to perform adequately is another issue. In the context of mortgages for low-income households, see for example Ambrose and Thibodeau (24). 3 On some of these equity or social arguments, see for example Grigsby and Bourassa (24). Our theoretical argument in favor of subsidies does not detract from potential implementation di culties. For an example of supply-side low income housing subsidies in the U.S. and its evaluation, see for example Cummings and DiPasquale (1999) and McClure (2). For a broader review of the main programs bene ting the low income housing market in the U.S., see Olson (21). 4 Assume for example that at time t =, the entrepreneur is a dynasty head who cares for the welfare of his o spring. In this context, the discount factor incorporates time preference as well as altruism. The 3

credit rating system means that the information on the quality of tenants is available to all landlords, not only to the landlord who rented a unit in the rst period to any particular tenant). At any given time t, a landlord will rent units to both new ( rst period) and old (second period) tenants. The number of landlords is K. As already mentioned, the landlords cannot identify the quality of new, rst period tenants. New tenants are therefore chosen randomly. After one period, "bad" tenants loose their unit since they did not pay their rent, while the identity of "good" tenants is common knowledge through the credit rating system. Let n i t be the number of new tenants chosen by landlord i at time t and let i t be the number of good tenants among them. If the number of landlords is large, we can use the following approximation KX i t = i=1 KX n i t (1) At the end of each period, good tenants are equaly distributed among each landlord. We will assume that the rent paid by good tenants is h. i=1 We could also assume that landlords wishing to keep good tenants will o er a reduction in rent in the second period, but this would not change the key results. What matters is that at the equilibrium, each landlord will ask for the same rent and good tenants will be distributed equally among all landlords. Speci cally, each landlord will have t 1 good tenants at time t with t 1 = (=K) P K i=1 ni t 1. Assume now that there exist 1 good tenants at time. For landlord i, the optimization problem is Eu i = max fn i tg 1 t=1 1X t u t 1 h + pn i th c t 1 + nt i df (p) ; (2) t= where Eu i represents the landlord s expected utility and is the discount factor. Using (1) in (2), we can rewrite the problem as Eu i = max fn i tg 1 t=1 1X t u t= P K k=1 nk t 1 K h + pn i th c P K k=1 nk t 1 Consider now the open loop Nash equilibrium of this problem. K + n i t!! df (p) : (3) The steady-state 4

equilibrium values are given by = u bn h [ + p] c (bn [1 + ]) ph c (bn [1 + ]) df (p) (4) + K h c (bn [1 + ]) u bn h [ + p] c (bn [1 + ]) df (p) Since u (),, and K are positive, and since h c () must also be positive, the second term of the right hand side of equation (4) is positive, which implies that the rst term is negative. The interpretation of (4) is that landlords equalize the expected marginal bene ts from identi ed good tenants in the second period, h K c () R 1 u () df (p), with the expected marginal cost of identifying those R 1 tenants, u () ph c () df (p). However, the fact that the rst term on the right hand side is negative also implies that when renting a unit to a new tenant, landlords make available units up to a point where the expected value in terms of marginal utility of the marginal bene t R 1 u () phdf (p) is lower than the expected value of the marginal cost R 1 u () c (bn [1 + ]) df (p). An alternative to the decentralized functioning of the market would be to have some agency intervening in order to maximize the joint expected utility of all landlords taken at once, by solving the following problem KX Eu k = max ffn i tg 1 t=1 gk i=1 k=1 KX i=1 1X t u t= P K k=1 nk t 1 The steady-state equilibrium of this problem is given by = K h + pn i th c P K k=1 nk t 1 K + n i t u en h [ + p] c (en [1 + ]) ph c (en [1 + ]) df (p) (6) + h c (en [1 + ]) u en h [ + p] c (en [1 + ]) df (p) By comparing (4) and (6), we can see that en > bn (since K > 1). (5) The reason why the coordinating agency performs better is due to the fact that individual landlords only consider their own expected marginal bene t in the second period when optimizing their behavior, h K c () R 1 u () df (p), while the coordinating agency takes into account the expected marginal bene t of all landlords taken togethger, namely h c () R 1 u () df (p). This situation is somewhat similar to Hardin s (1968) "tragedy of the commons" for renewable natural resources for which there is a free access. 5 Here, the common!! df (p) :

resource is the pool of identi ed good tenants to which all landlords have free (or quasi free) access. In the case of natural resources, the situation leads to over-extraction of the resources, while in our case, there is under-production of the common resource represented by the information on good tenants. If the demand for housing unit on the part of tenants is inelastic (everybody needs housing), the decentralized provision by risk averse landlords does not maximize social welfare. 3 Conclusion This notes provided a simple model under which the provision of low income housing units by risk averse private landlords is ine cient, as the marginal bene t from providing additional housing to the market would more than compensate for the cost of making these additional units available to tenants. A coordinating agency which would take into account the information generated by tenants on their ability to pay their rent would help to produce more housing units, and it would do so in a profitable way. The problem is that in the absence of such a coordinating agency, the information generated in the rst period on the quality of the new tenants is a public good which is not taken into account in the maximization behavior of decentralized landlords. It should be noted that the situation arises in part because both the rents and the quality of the housing units are regulated in the model. If we assume that tenants have an inelastic demand for housing (everybody needs a dwelling), prices would adjust upward to clear the market if there were no rent control. Alternatively, the cost of the housing units could adjust downward (lower quality) in order to clear the market at the rent ceiling. Yet in the low income housing market, we do typically have both rent ceilings and quality oors, so that the markets may not clear. A potential implication of our model is that in the absence of a coordinating agency (or if creating such an agency is not feasible), governments willing to minimize the proportion of the low income population without adequate housing could implement policies (e.g., production subsidies for private landlords or even public housing production) in order to acheive full e ciency in the functioning of the housing market. 6

References [1] Ambrose, B. W., and T. G. Thibodeau (24), Have the GSE A ordable Housing Goals Increased the Supply of Mortgage Credit?, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 34: 263-73. [2] Cummings, J. L., and D. DiPasquale (1999), The Low-Income Housing Tax Credit: An Analysis of the First Ten Years, Housing Policy Debate, 1: 251-37. [3] Grigsby, W. G., and Bourassa, S. C. (23), Trying to Understand Low-Income Housing Subsidies: Lessons from the United States, Urban Studies, 4:973-92. [4] Jovanovic, B. (1979), Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover, Journal of Political Economy, 87:972-99. [5] Hardin, G. (1968), The Tragedy of the Commons, Science, 162, 1243-1248. [6] Makdissi, P., and C. Téjédo (24), Un e et externe positif à l embauche: L amélioration de la connaissance de la qualité des travailleurs, Revue Économique, 55: 93-12. [7] Miller, R. A. (1984), Job Matching and Occupational Choice, Journal of Political Economy, 92:186-112. [8] McCall, B. P. (1991), A Dynamic Model of Occupational Choice, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 15:387-48. [9] McClure, K. (2), The Low-Income Housing Tax Credit as an Aid to Housing Finance: How Well Has It Worked?, Housing Policy Debate, 11: 91-114. [1] Olson, E. O. (21), Housing Programs for Low Income Households, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 828. 7