When Affordable Housing Moves in Next Door

Similar documents
NEIGHBORHOOD HOMES INVESTMENT ACT

Key Findings on the Affordability of Rental Housing from New York City s Housing and Vacancy Survey 2008

Comparative Study on Affordable Housing Policies of Six Major Chinese Cities. Xiang Cai

THE STATE OF THE NATION S HOUSING. Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University

Housing Costs and Policies

Dan Immergluck 1. October 12, 2015

Housing Indicators in Tennessee

Modeling Housing Affordability in Corpus Christi, Texas

Subsidized. Housing. in 2017

A Tale of Two Canadas

Northgate Mall s Effect on Surrounding Property Values

Glenmont Sector Plan Staff Draft AFFORDABLE HOUSING ANALYSIS

Effect of Public Housing on House Prices

2Should the next mayor require

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

Why are house prices so high in the Portland Metropolitan Area?

Little Haiti Community Needs Assessment: Housing Market Analysis December 2015

Briefing Book. State of the Housing Market Update San Francisco Mayor s Office of Housing and Community Development.

Highs & Lows of Floodplain Regulations

Housing Study & Needs Assessment

Glenmont Sector Plan Staff Draft AFFORDABLE HOUSING ANALYSIS

Integrating Housing into Regional Planning

ECONOMIC CURRENTS. Vol. 5 Issue 2 SOUTH FLORIDA ECONOMIC QUARTERLY. Key Findings, 2 nd Quarter, 2015

March 3, 2017 Prepared by

Re: Protecting HUD civil rights standards in the Rental Assistance Demonstration (RAD)

TOD and Equity. TOD Working Group. James Carras Carras Community Investment, Inc. August 7, 2015

Post-Katrina housing affordability challenges continue in 2008, worsening among Orleans Parish very low income renters

Housing Affordability in Lexington, Kentucky

SJC Comprehensive Plan Update Housing Needs Assessment Briefing. County Council: October 16, 2017 Planning Commission: October 20, 2017

Joint Center for Housing Studies Harvard University. Rachel Drew. July 2015

Affordable Housing in Scott County. Presented by: Julie Siegert, Housing Director Melissa Jensen, Homeownership Coordinator April 11, 2014

REGIONAL. Rental Housing in San Joaquin County

Economics of Inclusionary Housing Policies: Effects on Housing Prices

The supply of single-family homes for sale remains

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

Housing, Retail and Arts

State of the Nation s Housing 2008: A Preview

Housing and Equity Presentation

Rental Housing: Poised for a Return to Growth

Assessment Quality: Sales Ratio Analysis Update for Residential Properties in Indiana

RENTAL PRODUCTION AND SUPPLY

City of Exeter Housing Element

POLICY BRIEFING. ! Housing and Poverty - the role of landlords JRF research report

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

Subject. Date: 2016/10/25. Originator s file: CD.06.AFF. Chair and Members of Planning and Development Committee

Rent Control and its Implications to the Real Estate Industry

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

M A N H A T T A N 69 THE FURMAN CENTER FOR REAL ESTATE & URBAN POLICY. Financial District Greenwich Village/Soho

The rapidly rising price of single-family homes in. Change and Challenges East Austin's Affordable Housing Problem

Estimating Poverty Thresholds in San Francisco: An SPM- Style Approach

Briefing Book. State of the Housing Market Update San Francisco Mayor s Office of Housing and Community Development

CHAPTER 7 HOUSING. Housing May

San Francisco Bay Area to Santa Clara & San Benito Counties Housing and Economic Outlook

OVERVIEW OF RECENT/EXPECTED ECONOMIC/ HOUSING MARKET CONDITIONS

Business Analytics Center for Economic Research and Entrepreneurship (CERE)

San Francisco Bay Area to Sonoma County Housing and Economic Outlook

Housing Needs in Burlington s Downtown & Waterfront Areas

Perspective on FASB lease accounting changes Occupiers, owners and investors weigh in at JLL seminar

REPORT BY THE COMMITTEE ON HOUSING AND URBAN DEVELOPMENT THE MAPPING OF MANDATORY INCLUSIONARY HOUSING (MIH) AND THE EAST HARLEM REZONING

Multifamily Market Commentary November 2017

5 RENTAL AFFORDABILITY

COMMUNITY LAND TRUSTS:

APPENDIX B DESCRIPTION OF MAJOR FEDERAL LOW-INCOME HOUSING ASSISTANCE PROGRAMS

4. HOUSEHOLD INCOME AND AFFORDABILITY

School Quality and Property Values. In Greenville, South Carolina

Examining Policies to Reduce Homelessness Using a General Equilibrium Model of the Housing Market. Erin Mansur

New affordable housing production hits record low in 2014

UC Berkeley Fisher Center Working Papers

MEMORANDUM. Trip generation rates based on a variety of residential and commercial land use categories 1 Urban form and location factors the Ds 2

The Impact of Scattered Site Public Housing on Residential Property Values

Multifamily Market Analysis

MARKET WATCH: Dakota County

Measuring the Impact of The 606

No place to live. A UNISON survey report into the impact of housing costs on London s public service workers

2017 Sacramento Regional Affordable Housing Summit Monday, October 30, :35 a.m. 10:30 a.m.

The state of the nation s Housing 2011

While the United States experienced its larg

Assessment of Fair Housing Tool for Local Governments. Table of Contents

San Francisco Bay Area to Napa County Housing and Economic Outlook

Recommendations: The Task Force makes the following recommendations, for adoption by the Commission:

A VITAL RESOURCE FOR A DIVERSE NATION A DECADE OF BROAD-BASED DEMAND JOINT CENTER FOR HOUSING STUDIES OF HARVARD UNIVERSITY

TDHCA PROGRAM BROCHURE

SOUTHERN CALIFORNIA REGIONAL PROGRESS REPORT

Residential May Karl L. Guntermann Fred E. Taylor Professor of Real Estate. Adam Nowak Research Associate

The Impact of Market Rate Vacancy Increases Eleven-Year Report

Characteristics of Recent Home Buyers

H o u s i n g N e e d i n E a s t K i n g C o u n t y

ON THE HAZARDS OF INFERRING HOUSING PRICE TRENDS USING MEAN/MEDIAN PRICES

REAL ESTATE MARKET OVERVIEW 1 st Half of 2015

Affordability First: Concerns about Preserving Housing Options for Existing and New Residents on Atlanta s Westside

Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs

The Local Impact of Home Building in Douglas County, Nevada. Income, Jobs, and Taxes generated. Prepared by the Housing Policy Department

Public Review Draft. January 2007

The Metropolitan Transportation Plan/Sustainable Communities Strategy and the SACOG Region s Housing Market. July 2013

Housing the Region s Future Workforce SUMMER 2018

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

The Homebuyer s Guide to Community Land Trusts

How Fair Market Rents Limit Voucher Households to Live in Better Neighborhoods: The Case of Baltimore Metropolitan Area

San Francisco Bay Area to Marin, San Francisco, and San Mateo Counties Housing and Economic Outlook

Minneapolis St. Paul Residential Real Estate Index

Transcription:

October, 26 siepr.stanford.edu Stanford Institute for Policy Brief When Affordable Housing Moves in Next Door By Rebecca Diamond As housing costs rise and middleand mixed-class neighborhoods erode, more cities and towns are grappling with what to do about affordable housing. New York City Mayor Bill de Blasio came into office with a plan to build 2, units of affordable housing over a decade. Ed Lee, San Francisco s mayor, outlined his own initiative to create 3, units in the span of six years to preserve the city as a place where people from every background can call home. Subsidized housing policies often focus on easing the rents and mortgages of low-income families and giving them a shot at living in neighborhoods they could otherwise not afford. But construction of subsidized housing is a place-based policy. It not only influences a family s choice about where to live, it also affects a developer s decision about where to build and what types of families choose to live nearby. Those factors have an impact on the existing homes and residents, creating the challenge of determining how to best designate where affordable housing should go. In a paper I wrote with my Stanford colleague Tim McQuade, we quantify the costs and benefits of affordable housing construction to surrounding neighborhood residents and how they vary across demographically different neighborhoods. We found there is indeed an impact on neighborhoods when affordable housing moves in next door. But the effect depends on the neighborhood s initial income levels. Who wants affordable housing in their backyard? Our paper, Who Wants Affordable Housing in their Backyard? An Equilibrium Analysis of Low-Income Property Development, examines the neighborhood impacts of multifamily housing developments funded through the Low Income Housing Tax Credit (LIHTC). The program started in 986 and is now integral to federal housing policy. With an annual tax credit valued at more than $8 billion, the program paid for 2 percent of all multifamily developments between 987 and 28. To qualify for the federal tax credit proposed projects must rent to tenants who earn no more than 6 percent of the metropolitan area s median gross income. Additionally, developers must restrict rents in low-income units to 3 percent of the income limit for a minimum affordability period of 3 years. As one of the largest and longest-running affordable housing programs, LIHTC developments are ideal for studying affordable housing s impact on local neighborhoods and the community. About the Author Rebecca Diamond is a SIEPR Faculty Fellow and an Assistant Professor of Economics at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. She teaches Data and Decisions, and her current research studies the causes and consequence of segregation of households by income and education level across neighborhoods and labor markets. She was a Postdoctoral Fellow at SIEPR from 23 to 24. She received her PhD in Economics from Harvard University in 23 and her BS in Physics and Economics & Mathematics from Yale University in 27. We combine data on the location and funding dates for all LIHTC-funded projects, housing transaction data from 29 counties, and homebuyer race and income data to estimate the effects of LIHTC construction on the surrounding neighborhood. We quantify the impacts of LIHTC development by analyzing extremely local changes in the surrounding neighborhood before and after

Stanford Institute for construction of an LIHTC building versus trends in neighborhoods that are slightly farther away. This allows us to zoom in on the neighborhood changes caused by the LIHTC development. For richer or poorer Our estimates show that the impact of affordable housing construction has dramatically different effects on surrounding property values based on whether the affordable housing was built in relatively richer or poorer neighborhoods. Figure plots our estimated impacts of LIHTC development on house prices as a function of miles from the LIHTC development and years since the LIHTC development was built. These figures are stratified by the neighborhoods median income level, as measured in the 99 Census, before the LIHTC development. Figure.A shows that LIHTC construction in neighborhoods with a median income below $26, increases local property values by about 6. percent within one-tenth of a mile of the development site. LIHTC developments in middle-income neighborhoods have essentially no impact on house prices, as seen in Figure.B. In contrast, LIHTC construction in neighborhoods with median incomes above $38, leads to housing price declines of roughly 3 percent within that one-tenth of a mile radius. All of these effects decline as you move farther from the affordable housing sites, and they totally disappear three-quarters of a mile away. Since LIHTC causes house prices to appreciate in low-income areas, this shows the investment of new housing is a positive boost to the quality of the local neighborhood. But in wealthier areas, low-income housing appears to deflate local house prices. McQuade and I wanted to explore how LIHTC development leads to house price changes through its impacts on local neighborhood amenities. We dug into additional data to look at how LIHTC impacted a number of neighborhood characteristics. We found that the construction of an LIHTC development in a low-income area attracts more higher-income homebuyers to the neighborhood, compared with those who were buying houses in the area before the affordable housing was built. That s probably because the neighborhood improved and became more desirable thanks to lower crime rates, more retail shops, and an overall increase in the things that make for a better quality of life. Conversely, affordable housing development leads to more lowerincome families moving to wealthier areas where housing prices have fallen and become more affordable. We also found that affordable housing developments decrease racial segregation and reduce violent crime and vandalism within low-income areas. And they do not make crime increase in high-income neighborhoods. These results suggest real, concrete improvements in neighborhood quality in low-income communities. And in wealthier neighborhoods, we are unable to detect a concrete impact on a neighborhood other than creating a more economically diverse community. We combine the house price estimates with a model of neighborhood and housing choice to calculate the local values of having affordable housing in a particular type of neighborhood. We measure this dollar amount as how much extra households would be willing to pay for their home to have the opportunity to live near an LIHTC development. We infer these estimates by looking at the types of households that choose to move close to the new LIHTC sites. Our house price effect showed that houses close to the LIHTC site in a low-income area sell for a premium, while houses close to an LIHTC site in a high-income area sell at a discount. We infer households value of LIHTC proximity by measuring who chooses to live near these LIHTC sites and is willing to either pay more or less for a home in exchange for being closer to or farther away from an affordable housing development. We examine the benefits for homeowners, renters, and absentee landlords. 2

October, 26 Figure: Price Impact of LIHTC by Neighborhood Median Income (a) Q Income Neighorhoods (b) Q2 Income Neighorhoods.7.6..4.3.2..2....2.2.2.8.6.4.2.2.8.6.4.2 (c) Q3 Income Neighorhoods (d) Q4 Income Neighorhoods......2.2....3.2.3.2.8.6.4.2.2.2.8.6.4.2 Note: Household median income quartile cutoffs are $267, $3877, and $4642 in 22 dollars, as reported in the 99 Census block group of the LIHTC site. 3

Policy Brief What it s worth Our analysis reveals large possible societal gains from building affordable housing in low-income areas. Within the low-income neighborhoods, the average homeowner is willing to pay a one-time cost of $23,43 for the development of an LIHTC in his/her neighborhood. The average renter would be willing to pay a one-time cost of $6,2 and the average landlord would be willing to pay $6,. Within the higher-income areas, the average homeowner would be willing to pay $3,972 to deter LIHTC development and the average landlord would be willing to pay $2,46 to avoid development. Average renters, however, would be willing to pay $67 more to have affordable housing in their neighborhood because they find the rental discount they would receive for living close to the development more than offsets any drawbacks that might come from fewer neighborhood amenities. Adding these costs and benefits across all the households in these local neighborhoods, we find that the aggregate benefit to local homeowners from the typical LIHTC development in a low-income area is $7.9 million. The aggregate benefit to renters is $29.2 million and the benefit to landlords is $29. million. In total, the value of the neighborhood improvements caused by the construction of a single LIHTC site in a low-income area is equivalent to transferring those households $6.2 million. This is substantially more than the cost of development, which ranges from $ million to $2 million. These aggregate impacts to society are driven by the improvements or declines in the neighborhood amenities caused by the introduction of an LIHTC site. But building affordable housing in a high-income area leads to an aggregate loss of $2. million, with most of these losses being born by homeowners and landlords whose housing prices and rental markets fall. These placebased spillovers due to subsidized housing likely have large economic impacts across the United States, as federal, state, and local governments spend more than $97 billion dollars a year on different forms of housing assistance. The heterogeneity of LIHTC impacts across neighborhoods with differing incomes has policy implications when construction of affordable housing is viewed as a place-based policy. Moving LIHTC properties from higher-income to lower-income neighborhoods benefits the residents of each of those communities. Policy impact Of course, the neighborhood benefits of affordable housing must also be weighed against the cost and benefits of the neighborhood to the development s tenants. Chetty et al. (2) find that moving young children from poor public housing to areas with less poverty increases these children s future earnings by a present discounted value of $,. If we use this number to benchmark the potential gains to LIHTC tenants living in a high-income area versus a low-income neighborhood, and assume each apartment has two children in it, the average LIHTC development would improve the lifetime earnings potential of these children by $26.7 million. This is an underestimate of the total welfare benefits to these households, as it values only the increased earnings and not other benefits that have been documented, such as better measures of mental health and lower obesity rates (Kling et al. 27). The benefits to these low-income housing tenants more than offsets the losses to local residents in these highincome areas, making development in these higher-income areas look desirable. However, if placing such a property in a high-income area means that one less property must be allocated to a low-income area, then there is an opportunity cost of $6 million, which is more than four times the welfare benefits documented by Chetty et al. (26). This makes development of affordable housing in low-income areas appear to be a very effective policy in improving the economic welfare of many low-income 4

Stanford Institute for Policy Brief households, even when taking into account the current evidence on the benefits of moving low-income families to higher-income areas. We must add an additional caveat to these estimates due to the fact that there may likely be diminishing marginal returns to new housing in poor areas if these policies were scaled substantially; however, this is likely also true of the benefits estimated by Chetty et al. (26. Our results show that affordable housing development has large welfare impacts as a place-based policy, which more than offset the welfare impacts to tenants living in affordable housing. Given that the goals of many affordable housing policies aim to decrease income and racial segregation in housing markets, these goals might be better achieved by investing in affordable housing in low-income, high-minority areas, which will then lead to a more economically and racially diverse neighborhood.

Stanford Institute for Citations Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, and Lawrence F. Katz. The effects of exposure to better neighborhoods on children: New evidence from the Moving to Opportunity experiment. The American Economic Review 6.4 (26): 8-92. Diamond, Rebecca. The determinants and welfare implications of U.S. workers diverging location choices by skill: 98 2. The American Economic Review 6.3 (26): 479-24. Kling, Jeffrey R., Jeffrey B. Liebman, and Lawrence F. Katz. Experimental analysis of neighborhood effects. Econometrica 7. (27): 83-9. Schwartz, Amy Ellen, et al. The external effects of place-based subsidized housing. Regional Science and Urban Economics 36.6 (26): 679-77. Sinai, Todd, and Joel Waldfogel. Do low-income housing subsidies increase the occupied housing stock? Journal of Public Economics 89. (2): 237-264. About SIEPR We are Stanford University s hub for interdisciplinary research on economic policy. Our mission is to support research, train undergraduate and graduate students, and share knowledge that will lead to better economic policies in the United States and abroad. Policy Briefs SIEPR Policy Briefs summarize research by our affiliated faculty and researchers. They reflect the views and ideas of the author only. SIEPR is a nonpartisan research institute. For Additional Copies Please visit SIEPR.stanford.edu Location John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn Building 366 Galvez Street Stanford, CA 943-6 Online siepr.stanford.edu @siepr facebook.com/siepr/