The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

Similar documents
The Corner House and Relative Property Values

Is there a conspicuous consumption effect in Bucharest housing market?

Northgate Mall s Effect on Surrounding Property Values

Housing market and finance

What is the Value of a Name? Conspicuous Consumption and House Prices

Using Hedonics to Create Land and Structure Price Indexes for the Ottawa Condominium Market

Effects of Zoning on Residential Option Value. Jonathan C. Young RESEARCH PAPER

Volume 35, Issue 1. Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

EFFECT OF TAX-RATE ON ZONE DEPENDENT HOUSING VALUE

Procedures Used to Calculate Property Taxes for Agricultural Land in Mississippi

THE VALUE OF LEED HOMES IN THE TEXAS REAL ESTATE MARKET A STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF RESALE PREMIUMS FOR GREEN CERTIFICATION

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount?

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP /2/A/KMR Course Material Developed by Department of Economics, Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd

Sorting based on amenities and income

DEMAND FR HOUSING IN PROVINCE OF SINDH (PAKISTAN)

Historic Designation and Residential Property Values

The Impact of Urban Growth on Affordable Housing:

Estimating User Accessibility Benefits with a Housing Sales Hedonic Model

DATA APPENDIX. 1. Census Variables

School Quality and Property Values. In Greenville, South Carolina

Part 1. Estimating Land Value Using a Land Residual Technique Based on Discounted Cash Flow Analysis

The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s.

Geographic Variations in Resale Housing Values Within a Metropolitan Area: An Example from Suburban Phoenix, Arizona

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Regression Estimates of Different Land Type Prices and Time Adjustments

Over the past several years, home value estimates have been an issue of

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

Relationship of age and market value of office buildings in Tirana City

The Impact of Scattered Site Public Housing on Residential Property Values

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. The Demand for Educational Quality: Combining a Median Voter and Hedonic House Price Model

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

Re-sales Analyses - Lansink and MPAC

A Quantitative Approach to Gentrification: Determinants of Gentrification in U.S. Cities,

Micro Factors Causing Fall in Land Price in Mixture Area of Residence and Commerce

The Relationship Between Micro Spatial Conditions and Behaviour Problems in Housing Areas: A Case Study of Vandalism

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary

Small-Tract Mineral Owners vs. Producers: The Unintended Consequences of Well-Spacing Exceptions

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

LAND PRICE DYNAMICS IN A LARGE AUSTRALIAN URBAN HOUSING MARKET

Stat 301 Exam 2 November 5, 2013 INSTRUCTIONS: Read the questions carefully and completely. Answer each question and show work in the space provided.

Rockwall CAD. Basics of. Appraising Property. For. Property Taxation

ldepartment of Agriculturaland AppliedEconomical

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

1. There must be a useful number of qualified transactions to infer from. 2. The circumstances surrounded each transaction should be known.

Efficiency in the California Real Estate Labor Market

Hunting the Elusive Within-person and Between-person Effects in Random Coefficients Growth Models

Regional Housing Trends

Valuation of Amenities in the Housing Market of Jönköping: A Hedonic Price Approach

THE ACCURACY OF COMMERCIAL PROPERTY VALUATIONS

Ludgvan Parish HOUSING NEED SURVEY. Report Date: 21 st January Version: 1.2 Document Status: Final Report

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

2011 ASSESSMENT RATIO REPORT

VALUATION CONSIDERATIONS AND METHODS FOR A PATENT VALUATION ANALYSIS

Security Measures and the Apartment Market

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

Analysing lessee financial statements and Non-GAAP performance measures

Hennepin County Economic Analysis Executive Summary

Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions

On the Choice of Tax Base to Reduce. Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the Context of Electricity. Generation

A. K. Alexandridis University of Kent. D. Karlis Athens University of Economics and Business. D. Papastamos Eurobank Property Services S.A.

Estimating the Value of the Historical Designation Externality

Taking Advantage of the Wholesale Discount for Large Timberland Transactions

A Real-Option Based Dynamic Model to Simulate Real Estate Developer Behavior

Use of the Real Estate Market to Establish Light Rail Station Catchment Areas

Analysis on Natural Vacancy Rate for Rental Apartment in Tokyo s 23 Wards Excluding the Bias from Newly Constructed Units using TAS Vacancy Index

While the United States experienced its larg

April 12, The Honorable Martin O Malley And The General Assembly of Maryland

Do Family Wealth Shocks Affect Fertility Choices?

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore

Initial sales ratio to determine the current overall level of value. Number of sales vacant and improved, by neighborhood.

THE EFFECT OF PROXIMITY TO PUBLIC TRANSIT ON PROPERTY VALUES

Demonstration Properties for the TAUREAN Residential Valuation System

Chapter 13. The Market Approach to Value

by Dr. Michael Sklarz and Dr. Norman Miller October 13, 2016 Introduction

Rental Housing and the Natural Vacancy Rate

Gregory W. Huffman. Working Paper No. 01-W22. September 2001 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235

CLTS seminar 24 January 2014

Assessment-To-Sales Ratio Study for Division III Equalization Funding: 1999 Project Summary. State of Delaware Office of the Budget

The Honorable Larry Hogan And The General Assembly of Maryland

Heterogeneity in the Neighborhood Spillover Effects of. Foreclosed Properties

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Description of IHS Hedonic Data Set and Model Developed for PUMA Area Price Index

2012 Profile of Home Buyers and Sellers New Jersey Report

Effects Of Zoning On Housing Option Value Prathamesh Muzumdar, Illinois State University, Normal, USA

Cook County Assessor s Office: 2019 North Triad Assessment. Norwood Park Residential Assessment Narrative March 11, 2019

Evaluating Unsmoothing Procedures for Appraisal Data

Recommendations for COD Standards. Robert J. Gloudemans Almy, Gloudemans, Jacobs & Denne. for. New York State Office of Real Property Services

Waiting for Affordable Housing in NYC

Land-Use Regulation in India and China

Interest Rates and Fundamental Fluctuations in Home Values

ASSESSMENT REVIEW BOARD. The City of Edmonton JASPER AVENUE Assessment and Taxation Branch

Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States

PROJECT H.O.M.E. S ECONOMIC AND FISCAL IMPACT ON PHILADELPHIA NEIGHBORHOODS

EXPLANATION OF MARKET MODELING IN THE CURRENT KANSAS CAMA SYSTEM

Transcription:

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 1 The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham Durham Research Paper Michael Ni

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 2 Introduction Real estate economics raises an interesting question about how markets value relative house size in a neighborhood. What do consumers more highly value, a relatively small house in a neighborhood of large houses or a relatively large house in a neighborhood of small houses? This has been a paradoxical question that has resulted in a variety of contradicting answers by both real estate agents and economists. Real estate agents have frequently given contradicting recommendations regarding this debate, arguing that the most profitable deal is to buy a low-end house in a top-tier neighborhood while also maintaining that buying the largest house in a neighborhood results in the most cost-efficient purchase. Likewise, academic literature has produced many perplexing theories regarding the valuation of homes based on relative size. Atypicality, conspicuous consumption, and fiscal capitalization are three prominent rationales for how markets value house size relative to the surrounding neighborhood composition. In the present study, I will utilize public data (obtained from Zillow) on housing sales in six different Durham neighborhoods to estimate the effects of relative size of houses on their selling price.

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 3 Theoretical Framework The following section contains a detailed description of each of the three popular theories: atypicality, conspicuous consumption, and fiscal capitalization. The summaries for each theory and their respective effects on housing prices are summarized in Table 1. I) Atypicality Effect The atypicality effect is based on Haurin s model (1988), which explains why houses with unusual attributes take longer to sell (Turnbull et al, 2006). In essence, there are few buyers who have a strong preference for atypical houses, therefore resulting in a longer time for the market to match the supply of these atypical houses with prospective buyers. However, Haurin s model focuses entirely on the selling time of the house, whereas in the present model (Turnbull et al, 2006), we shift focus instead to the price effects of atypicality. To begin, imagine a particular neighborhood comprised of a variety of different house sizes. Let s suppose that the type of buyer who is most attracted to the houses in this neighborhood is the type who most prefers the average-size house in this neighborhood j, Ĥ j. Let P denote this buyer s valuation of a house with size H (which may or may not differ from Ĥ j ). The indirect utility function for this type of buyer is V(P, δ), where the difference in house size H from the average for the neighborhood is given by the parameter: δ = H - Ĥ j. The assumption of this atypicality model is therefore, ( V/ δ )< 0, indicating that atypical houses in the neighborhood (either larger than average or smaller than average) will result in lower offers from a typical buyer. The competitive pricing condition is V(P,δ) =U 0,

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 4 where U 0 is the buyer s opportunity cost (alternatively, the expected utility from purchasing elsewhere). By implicitly differentiating the competitive pricing condition, we can compare the value of any house in a heterogeneous neighborhood with an identical house in a different, homogenous neighborhood. Using the properties of indirect utility ( V/ P = H), we derive the pricing effect of atypicality as. This equation implies that houses that are either larger or smaller than the average for the neighborhood will sell at a discount (Turnbull et al, 2006). Intuitively, this derivation is logical: if larger/smaller than average houses are considered atypical by potential buyers, then they will take longer to find a suitable match, and therefore they will be sold at a lower price when compared to similarly sized houses in a homogenous neighborhood (when controlling for time on the market). I) Conspicuous Consumption Effect Under the parameters of the conspicuous consumption effect, which stems from the ideas originally developed by Veblen (1899), consumers obtain additional utility from demonstrating their greater affluence by buying a house that is larger than surrounding houses (Turnbull et al, 2006). This effect has been popularized in contemporary real estate culture as the pride of ownership, whereby owners of larger houses in a neighborhood obtain greater utility from showcasing their wealth. In terms of the capitalization model outlined above, the assumption of the conspicuous consumption model is ( V / δ) > 0. Differentiating the competitive pricing condition yields ( P / δ) > 0. The implication of this

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 5 equation is that there is greater value placed on houses that are larger-than-average (δ> 0), resulting in a premium on their sale prices compared to an otherwise identical house in a homogenous neighborhood. The reverse logic applies for the relatively small house in a neighborhood of larger houses: a smaller-than-average house signals lower wealth (δ< 0), thereby reducing the inherent utility and causing these houses to be sold at a discount (Turnbull et al, 2006). II) Fiscal Capitalization Effect The Fiscal Capitalization effect can effectively be summarized by Hamilton s demonstration (1976) that local property tax can lead to price differentials for large or small houses in heterogeneous communities not observed for the same size houses in homogeneous communities (Turnbull et al, 2006). Although his formulation was originally applied to housing variation within a federal jurisdiction, the implications can also apply to variation in housing size within the context of a local neighborhood. To illustrate this effect, assume that the bundle of all government services provided by property taxes, G, is the same for all households (regardless of variations in size), and that M i is the money budget for individual households. 1) Buyer s utility for y (non-housing consumption) and H i (housing) U(y, H i, G). 2) Gross-of-Property tax unit price of house H i (1+t)P i 3) The utility for house H i U(M i (1+t)P i H i, H i, G)

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 6 Therefore, property tax rate (t m ) needed for government services (G) in a heterogeneous housing community is given by where the superscript m indicates market values in the heterogeneous community. Using similar logic, the property tax rate needed for an equivalent level of government services in a homogenous community can be derived: where N represents the total number of houses in the community. The competitive pricing condition for a prospective buyer in the heterogeneous neighborhood is given by U(M i (1 + t m )P i m H i, H i, G) = U(M i (1+ t i )P i H i, H i, G). Consequently, the pricing condition requires (1 + t m )P i m H i = (1+ t i )P i i H i After substituting with the previous equations and rearranging the variables, we arrive at (P i m P i i )NH i = 1 (P i m H i )/(PH*)

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 7 where PH* is the market value of the average size house in the heterogeneous neighborhood. Thus, in the heterogeneous community, the three sizes of houses (H L > H* > H S ) yield the following unit price relationship: P L m < P* < P S m. This equation implies that large houses have lower unit prices, and small houses have higher unit prices when compared with the average house in a heterogeneous neighborhood. Essentially, larger houses suffer from a larger effective property tax bill for comparable services, as a result of having a greater taxable value (Turnbull et al, 2006). Therefore, the capitalization of this net fiscal disadvantage for relatively larger houses in the community results in relatively larger houses being sold at a discount and relatively smaller houses being sold at a premium. Table 1: Summary of the Economic Theories and Their Price Effects

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 8 Empirical Analysis In the empirical study, I used the public online database Zillow to collect a sample of single-family, owner-occupied housing transactions undertaken in Durham, North Carolina. The data set covers 60 total transactions over the past 36 months (April 2010 through April 2013), and is sub-categorized into 6 distinct, heterogeneous neighborhoods with varying house sizes. The neighborhoods are all roughly one quarter-mile in diameter, and represent a random sample of the typical Durham community (refer to the Appendix for specific locations of each region). Table 2 summarizes the means and standard deviations of the pertinent variables used in this study. Sales price, number of days on the market (DOM), the square footage of living area (Livarea), lot area, and year of construction are all directly obtained for each individual transaction through Zillow. The Age is calculated as the difference between the date of construction and the date of sale. The Discount variable is calculated as: 1- selling price/listing price. The most important variables that are central to this study are those that measure the size of the house relative to the other houses in the immediate neighborhood. I have used six independent, binary dummy variables (not shown in the tables) to control for the neighborhood/location designation of each of the homes. Indexing all houses within a quarter-mile radius of house i by J, the standardized measure which I used to measure relative house size is:

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 9 The relative size variables, Larger i and Smaller i, are continuous variables intended to measure the deviations of individual house sizes from the Local Mean Living Area, and are defined as the absolute value of Localsize i. Therefore: Larger i = Localsize i for Localsize i > 0, and =0 otherwise Smaller i = Localsize i for Localsize i < 0, and =0 otherwise. I estimated the effects of the various housing characteristics on selling price using multiple regression analysis. The equation is based on contemporary hedonic pricing models, with the log of sales price as a function of DOM, house characteristics, neighborhood characteristics (dummy), and time trends (36 months) to capture broad market conditions. The results of the regression are reported in Table 2 (with the exception of the six dummy variables). In the current model, it can be seen that older houses sell for less than newer houses, and that net area is more valuable than living area. However, the relative size variables are the main variables of interest to this study, and their positive coefficients indicate that both larger and smaller houses sell at a premium relative to equivalently sized houses in a homogenous neighborhood. The quadratic term on these relative size variables indicate that the price premium increases at a decreasing rate as the size differential between the houses and their neighborhood competitors increase.

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 10 Conclusion The larger and smaller price effect estimates do not support Haurin s atypicality hypothesis (which state that larger and smaller houses would both be sold at discounted prices), but are consistent with the combined theories of Veblen s Conspicuous Consumption Theory and Hamilton s Fiscal Capitalization Theory. The negative price effect of fiscal capitalization on relatively larger houses is overshadowed by the positive price effect from conspicuous consumption. Similarly, the negative price effect of conspicuous consumption on relatively smaller houses is overshadowed by the positive price effects of fiscal capitalization. Although the results are not consistent with Haurin s Atypicality hypothesis, we cannot say with certainty that its effects are not present. Instead, we can only conclude that, if atypicality effects do exist, they are dominated by the stronger forces of conspicuous consumption and fiscal capitalization. However, it is also important to note that the empirical evidence offered here is the result of a very small sample size (N=60) collected with very limited resources. Additionally, the sample only pertains to a small cluster of neighborhoods in a small region (Durham), making it very difficult to generalize these findings to a national scale. To build on to the findings of this study, it is imperative in future empirical studies to extract MLA data on a larger scale in order to determine if the previous relationships are generalizable to other regions. An extended analysis could also incorporate additional variables related to the demographics of the neighborhoods in order to arrive at more precise and accurate results.

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 11 References Clapp, J.M. 2007. The Influence of School District Performance and Demographic Composition on Property Values. Economics Working Papers. Hamilton, B.W. 1976. Capitalization of Intrajurisdictional Differences in Local Tax Prices. American Economic Review 66: 743-753. Haurin, D. 1988. The Duration of Marketing Time of Residential Housing. AREUEA Jouranl 16: 396-410. Turnbull, G.K. 2006. Big House, Little House: Relative Size and Value. Real Estate Economics 34: 439-456. Turnbull, G.K. and J. Dombrow. 2006. Spatial Competition and Shopping Externalities: Evidence from the Housing Market. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 32: 391-408. Veblen, T. 1899. Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: MacMillan.

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 12 Appendix Table 2 Description of Variables and Summary Statistics Description Average Std. Dev. Min Max Price Selling Price of Home 60233.33333 54246.64847 7500 275000 DOM Days on the market 246.3166667 283.5414352 18 1188 Livarea Square feet of living area 1408.55 379.0704252 1000 2780 Lotarea Square feet of lot area 7871.766667 3984.197826 3920 30056 Lotsqft Square feet of lot size/10,000 0.787176667 0.398419783 0.392 3.0056 Netarea Square feet of other area 6463.216667 3957.996292 2295 28952 Year Year of construction 1945.683333 40.29993131 1900 2011 Age Age of House 67.31666667 40.29993131 2 113 Discount % discount from list price 0.077083333 0.418414574-0.759 0.865 Month Time Trend Variable 24.65 8.996845021 2 35 Averagearea Average area of houses 1408.55 163.0139097 1146.1 1677.4 Localsize Deviation from local mean living area 9.02056E-18 0.227484998-0.38356981 0.657326815 Larger Positive deviations from LMLA 0.084474597 0.163382959 0 0.657326815 Smaller Negative deviations from LMLA 0.084474597 0.102672395 0 0.38356981 Table 3 Results for Log of Sales Price Equation Coefficients t Stat Intercept 37.920 2,531.898 DOM 0.017 3,634.370 *** LivArea -0.018-0.001 NetArea 0.004 0.000 Age -0.006-155.959 *** Month 0.013 72.753 *** Lotsqft -47.710 0.000 Larger 2.862 70.360 *** Smaller 3.989 75.129 *** Lotsqft^2-0.072-19.085 *** Larger^2-3.821-59.517 *** Smaller^2-9.501-61.242 *** Adjusted R^2 0.780 Key ***=indicates significance at the 1% level

TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 13 Neighborhood 1 Neighborhood 4 Neighborhood 2 Neighborhood 5 Neighborhood 3 Neighborhood 6