The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation

Similar documents
Northgate Mall s Effect on Surrounding Property Values

Status of HUD-Insured (or Held) Multifamily Rental Housing in Final Report. Executive Summary. Contract: HC-5964 Task Order #7

The Impact of Scattered Site Public Housing on Residential Property Values

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Affordable Housing Policy. Economics 312 Martin Farnham

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

While the United States experienced its larg

WIndicators. Housing Issues Affecting Wisconsin. Volume 1, Number 4. Steven Deller, Todd Johnson, Matt Kures, and Tessa Conroy

WRT. October 16, Arthur Collins President Collins Enterprises, LLC 2001 West Main Street, Suite 175 Stamford, CT 06902

When Affordable Housing Moves in Next Door

Chapter 13. Why Is Housing Different? Why is Housing Different? Questions to Address. Questions to Address

Economic justification of non-commercial buildings renovation or substitutional construction

FILED: NEW YORK COUNTY CLERK 10/25/ :59 PM INDEX NO /2016 NYSCEF DOC. NO. 11 RECEIVED NYSCEF: 10/25/2016

Subject. Date: 2016/10/25. Originator s file: CD.06.AFF. Chair and Members of Planning and Development Committee

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

Is there a conspicuous consumption effect in Bucharest housing market?

Analysis Prepared by David L. Sjoquist and Robert J. Eger III

Estimating the Value of the Historical Designation Externality

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

CLASS 8 ELIGIBILITY BULLETIN

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

THE IMPACT OF RESIDENTIAL REAL ESTATE MARKET BY PROPERTY TAX Zhanshe Yang 1, a, Jing Shan 2,b

Housing Price Forecasts. Illinois and Chicago PMSA, December 2015

Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB)

6 April 2018 KEY POINTS

Part 1. Estimating Land Value Using a Land Residual Technique Based on Discounted Cash Flow Analysis

The Economic Impacts Of the Historic District In Charleston, South Carolina. Economics Department Honors Thesis Presented on April 29, 2005

Urban Land Policy and Housing for Poor and Women in Amhara Region: The Case of Bahir Dar City. Eskedar Birhan Endashaw

[Re. Docket No. FR 6123-A-01] Affirmatively Furthering Fair Housing: Streamlining and Enhancements (the Streamlining Notice )

Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions

Zoning Analysis. 2.0 Residential Use. 1.0 Introduction

ROOSEVELT CITY. Finally, STRATEGIC ISSUES are ideas the City might want to consider when they conduct a formal update to their plan.

California Real Estate License Exam Prep: Unlocking the DRE Salesperson and Broker Exam 4th Edition

HOUSING & RESIDENTIAL AREAS

Re: Proposed Accounting Standards Update, Applying Variable Interest Entity Guidance to Common Control Leasing Arrangements

How Severe is the Housing Shortage in Hong Kong?

EFFECT OF TAX-RATE ON ZONE DEPENDENT HOUSING VALUE

to provide background about the America Park Housing Development and stakeholders;

Systemic Approaches to Vacancy & Blight:

A Historical Perspective on Illinois Farmland Sales

Essentials of Real Estate Economics

PROPERTY TAX IS A PRINCIPAL REVENUE SOURCE

820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Determinants of residential property valuation

Filling the Gaps: Active, Accessible, Diverse. Affordable and other housing markets in Johannesburg: September, 2012 DRAFT FOR REVIEW

Relationship of age and market value of office buildings in Tirana City

Myth Busting: The Truth About Multifamily Renters

A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County

TANGIBLE CAPITAL ASSETS

RESEARCH ON PROPERTY VALUES AND RAIL TRANSIT

BUSI 330 Suggested Answers to Review and Discussion Questions: Lesson 1

31 July 2014 Japan s Modified International Standards (JMIS): Accounting Standards Comprising IFRSs and the ASBJ Modifications

Financial Analysis of Urban Development Opportunities in the Fairfield and Gonzales Communities, Victoria BC

The survey also examines the underlying causes of FVM and impairment audit

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA. Cascade: No. 75, Fall Land Banks as a Redevelopment Tool

CLARK COUNTY NEIGHBORHOOD REVITALIZATION PLAN. Effective Date. January 1, Revised

Hennepin County Economic Analysis Executive Summary

Economics of Leasing. Introduction

SCOTTISH GOVERNMENT RESPONSE TO PRIVATE RENTED HOUSING (SCOTLAND) BILL STAGE 1 REPORT

Dan Immergluck 1. October 12, 2015

IFRS 16 LEASES. Page 1 of 21

Chapter 11 Investments in Noncurrent Operating Assets Utilization and Retirement

LISC Land Data Initiative. Presented by Teal Horsman, The Catalytic Fund

Extending the Right to Buy

AMERICAN SOCIETY OF APPRAISERS. Procedural Guidelines. PG-2 Valuation of Partial Ownership Interests

Housing. Imagine a Winnipeg...: Alternative Winnipeg Municipal Budget

Response to Communities and Local Government Committee Inquiry into capacity in the homebuilding industry

Introduction Public Housing Education Ethnicity, Segregation, Transactions. Neighborhood Change. Drivers and Effects.

Following is an example of an income and expense benchmark worksheet:

CONNECTING ARLINGTON S POLICY FRAMEWORK TO THE RESIDENTIAL PARKING WORKING GROUP

Assessment Quality: Sales Ratio Analysis Update for Residential Properties in Indiana

Brick, Mortar, and More

ASSESSMENT METHODOLOGY

Solutions to Questions

Why are house prices so high in the Portland Metropolitan Area?

Use of Comparables. Claims Prevention Bulletin [CP-17-E] March 1996

Florida Brownfields Association

Stockton Unified School District Instructional Guide for Economics Traditional Schedule

Understanding The 606 s impact on the surrounding neighborhood s housing market

acuitas, inc. s survey of fair value audit deficiencies August 31, 2014 pcaob inspections methodology description of a deficiency

AGRICULTURAL Finance Monitor

Housing Affordability in Lexington, Kentucky

BUSI 398 Residential Property Guided Case Study

2013 Wisconsin Real Estate and Economic Outlook Conference: City of Milwaukee Interventions in the Wake of Private Market Failures

HOMESTEAD PLAN. City of Buffalo

Ontario Rental Market Study:

File Reference No : Leases (Topic 842): a Revision of the 2010 Proposed Accounting Standards Update, Leases (Topic 840)

Findings: City of Johannesburg

Housing Price Forecasts. Illinois and Chicago PMSA, January 2018

Illustrations of Financing and Tax Transfers in Owner Financed Real Estate Sales

Demonstration Properties for the TAUREAN Residential Valuation System

Residential Neighborhoods and Housing

Evaluation of Vertical Equity in Residential Property Assessments in the Lake Oswego and West Linn Areas

SCHOOL RESOURCE OFFICERS (SROs) AND THE ARMING OF SCHOOL TEACHERS OR ADMINISTRATORS AS RESPONSES TO SCHOOL SHOOTINGS:

1. INTRODUCTION .., Since, Sri Lanka's economy turn in to!tee market economy policy, there has been a. 1.1 Background

The Value of Real Estate

Old Neighborhoods and Housing Provide New Models for the Future.

The Corner House and Relative Property Values

Transcription:

The Park Place Economist Volume 12 Issue 1 Article 16 2004 The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation '05 Illinois Wesleyan University Recommended Citation Romero '05, Ana Maria (2004) "The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation," The Park Place Economist: Vol. 12 Available at: http://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace/vol12/iss1/16 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by The Ames Library, the Andrew W. Mellon Center for Curricular and Faculty Development, the Office of the Provost and the Office of the President. It has been accepted for inclusion in Digital Commons @ IWU by the faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact digitalcommons@iwu.edu. Copyright is owned by the author of this document.

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation Abstract This paper argues that assigning historic district designation to a neighborhood or urban area increases the value of properties within the district and revitalizes the area economically because of the positive externalities associated with historic districts. It focuses almost exclusively on the economic and commercial reasons for why a historic property should be conserved and how policies to do so should be implemented. This article is available in The Park Place Economist: http://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace/vol12/iss1/16

The Positive Externalities of Historic District Designation I. INTRODUCTION This paper argues that assigning historic district designation to a neighborhood or urban area increases the value of properties within the district and revitalizes the area economically because of the positive externalities associated with historic districts. It focuses almost exclusively on the economic and commercial reasons for why a historic property should be conserved and how policies to do so should be implemented. There are many reasons why historical buildings should be preserved. First, they have an aesthetic value. Historic buildings are often more interesting than the new, industrial buildings, housing and shopping centers (Tiesdell, 1996). In our constantly changing world, we need reminders of how things were and preserving historic buildings provides an anchor to the past, as well as an incentive to the future. This argument relates to the argument for architectural diversity. Historic buildings provide a contrast to more modern structures, which make them relatively more appealing. Arguments can also be made that historic buildings have functional diversity, resource value, value for continuity of cultural heritage, and economic and commercial value (Tiesdell, 1996). II. PREVIOUS LITERATURE In our constantly changing world, we need reminders of how things were, and preserving historic buildings provides an anchor to the past, as well as an incentive to the future. In a context where public funds cannot subsidize all the required and desired preservation, economic and commercial justifications for preservation and conservation must ultimately underpin all other reasons (Tiesdell, 1996). Rypkema (1992) argues that for any commodity to have economic value, it must possess the following four characteristics: scarcity, purchasing power, desire, and utility. Historic buildings usually possess the first two characteristics, but they are generally lacking the last two. Furthermore, because of the obsolescence of a building, its utility will diminish greatly over time. For commercial desire to exist, there must be financial utility to investors. These two factors make it difficult to match the needs of the investors with the needs of the community for preservation. According to Lichfield (1998), the obsolescence of buildings and areas is expressed in a mismatch between the services offered by the building and the needs of the investors. The purpose of revitalization is to reconcile this mismatch. Revitalization involves both the renewal of the physical aspect of buildings, as well as a deeper economic revitalization, which is intended to be long lasting. Economic revitalization is required because, in the long term, the productive utilization of the property is what pays for the public cost of revitalization 71 The Park Place Economist, Volume XII

(Tiesdell, 1996). Although it is argued that historic buildings are part of the real estate market, and as such, they should be left alone so that the market adjusts the prices to the most profitable and efficient use of land, a free market economy ignores the social needs of the community. Historic buildings and areas have certain intangible value to society. Their loss or destruction results in a loss of welfare for society (Tiesdell 1996). This value relates back to the values associated with historic buildings and areas in the first part of this paper. The social value that historic buildings and areas possess is the positive externality effect. In the land market, any intervention to adjust demand and supply will create new conditions for decision-making, which, in turn, will modify land values and land-use patterns. Public intervention into the private property market through conservation and preservation controls is therefore a way to make building owners more aware of the social value of their buildings (Tiesdell, 1996). Some argue that because of government intervention, homeowners and owners of historic buildings would not be able to obtain the maximum return for their property. However, it is argued that the positive externalities of the designation increase the overall return to the community; this overrides the loss of the private owner. Thus, in terms of historic urban quarters, there is further economic justification for land use and preservation controls: to create and maintain a context that sustains and reinforces the composite value of the area (Tiesdell, 1996). For economic revitalization to take place, the entire area needs to be considered. This is called area-based renewal. The strategies used to implement area-based renewal focus on unblocking supply-side constraints of land in order to promote economic revitalization. The rationale is that growth can be stimulated by improvements in the supply of land, Public intervention into the private property market through conservation and preservation controls is therefore a way to make building owners more aware of the social value of their buildings. labor, capital and entrepreneurship (Solesbury, 1990). Thus, when an area is assigned as a historic district, an attempt is being made to improve the area as a whole, not only a specific building site. By attempting to preserve the entire area, the loss in expected return on each building is minimized. III. FORMAL MODEL Having laid the groundwork for why an area should be preserved if it contains significant historic properties, this issue needs to be analyzed from a more formal economic viewpoint, specifically through the marginal benefit-marginal cost model. The hypothesis is that when an area is assigned as a historic district, the marginal benefit of owners within the district will increase because of the positive externalities associated with historic district designation. Marginal cost will also increase because of all the regulations and restrictions that the designation implies. Historic property should be treated in this context as a merit good because of the positive external benefit it provides to society. Therefore, government subsidy is justified. The idea behind this is that by designating an area as a historic district, the government can help subsidize renovations made to the property either through subsidies or tax cuts. By doing so, the government is helping the owners maintain the external appearance of the property, which slows down the retirement of historic property, thus contributing to neighborhood renovation. So, there are two benefits related with historic districts. The owner benefits because the property is increasing in value. The area benefits because it will be economically revitalized by the designation. The costs of historic district designation are that once a property is considered part of a historic district, the owner loses a great deal of control over The Park Place Economist, Volume XII 72

the external appearance of the property, as well as its economic uses. As part of a historic district, a property s external appearance needs to meet certain standards and cannot be modified. In addition, the use of the property cannot be modified. As a result, owners of historic property experience a loss, since their property could possibly earn a higher economic return if used differently. However, marginal benefit is greater relative to marginal cost, which will increase demand for historic properties. This increase in demand will become evident by rising property values after the designation. One can assume that the supply of historic property is highly inelastic, mainly because of its scarcity. Furthermore, the rise in property value also signifies that consumers will be paying a price higher than the actual physical cost of the property. The premium paid is the social need of the community, relating to the social and cultural value of the historic building. The increase in property values in the area will benefit the area and lead to its economic revitalization if it is a commercial district. In conclusion, by examining the evidence, one should use an increase in property values as a measure to evaluate the effectiveness of historic district designation. IV. EVIDENCE Lockhard and Hinds find that districting has a significant positive effect on the restoration of residential properties of average quality (Nelson, 1991). However, once architectural quality is held constant, historic district designation did not lead to increased investment in two of the three groups sampled. Denniss (1991) concludes that the possible physical and economic benefits of historic district designation are abundantly clear, but there are nagging doubts about whether the act of designation should lead or follow reinvestment trends in older neighborhoods possessing historic attributes. In their evaluation of the effect of historic district designation in New Orleans, Laska, Seaman, and McSeveney (1982) find that proximity of residences and neighborhood to such districts is a weak indicator for renovation. All these studies fail to associate district designation and property values in ways that control for other factors. They fail to control for the influences of neighborhood household income, proximity to the city center, property size and dimensions, or even the date of transaction to account for changing value attributable solely to the passage of time (Nelson, 1991). Benson and Klein (1998) analyze the effect of historic district designation on residential property values in two Cleveland neighborhoods. They find that sales prices in the historic district fall short of initial expectations. They conclude that the local market perceived that the local neighborhoods were in economic decline and historic districting did little to alter this perception (Nelson, 1991). Ahern, Schaeffer and Milerick (1991) conducted a case study and examined the change in property values in the Chicago area. Ahern (1985) first found that with standard regression analysis, historic district preservation in the Chicago neighborhood studies, designation was only significant before the 1980 s. Their empirical study in 1991 represents an example in which preservation activities have positive economic impacts. However, they concluded that if the policies associated with a historic district were too restrictive, the market value of the properties would decline. Asabere and Huffman (1994) studied several neighborhoods in Philadelphia and found that residential property located in a federally certified district carried roughly a 26% price premium relative to property located outside of a federally certified district. Because investment tax credits, generally assumed to be the benefit associated with federal historic districting, are unavailable to owners who rehabilitate owner-occupied property, they attributed the premium to the positive externality effects that flow from the historic designation of a district or zone. Ford (1989) found that if neighborhood and house characteristics are held constant, the effect on prices of a historic district designation is positive. Houses in areas with a historic district designation have higher transaction prices than they would if they were located in similar non-historic districts (Ford, 1989). Her hypothesis that homebuyers are willing 73 The Park Place Economist, Volume XII

to pay more for a house if they can be assured that the surrounding houses will remain unchanged over time is supported. Nelson and Talley (1991) conducted a case study in Atlanta, Georgia. They were more concerned with the economic revitalization of the neighborhoods being studied. Their analysis indicated that historic district designation with the attendant investment benefits to property owners and public investment has a coincidental effect on commercial property values. They concluded that although historic district designation is a powerful urban planning tool, it should be used mainly as a supplement to other policies. V. CONCLUSION In conclusion, the evidence of whether historic districts create positive externalities and therefore, higher prices, is inconclusive. Some of the evidence suggests that there are no benefits to historic district designation and, in some cases, the restrictive policies of the designation actually lessen property values. Other evidence suggests that there is a premium to buildings located within a district, but the premium is not related to the social need to preserve the building. Instead it is related to the positive externality effect of living in a neighborhood where all other neighboring houses are required to maintain a certain standard. Theoretically, renovation should imply many economic benefits to an area, but evidence to support this is also inconclusive. Historic district designation may not be what leads to the economic revitalization of an area, but it can be a tool to speed up the renovation. Therefore, there are doubts of whether it should only be applied to neighborhoods that are already experiencing renovation. The implications these results have for policymakers is that historic districts are not a panacea for urban decline unless accompanied by a serious interest in dealing with many other issues (Benson, 1988). It can be argued that historic district designation is a powerful tool only if it is designed to meet the individual and unique needs of the area in question. Longrange objectives and goals to make the designation more compatible with modern and contemporary urban standards should be developed and implemented. Also, the historical value of the building or area should be taken into consideration. Not every historic area can be preserved and only those that prove to have an economic utility should be. REFERENCES Ahern, Cecily P. The Economics of Preservation: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Historic District Designation on Property Values in Chicago Neighborhood. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois, 1985. Asabere, Paul.; Huffman, Forrest E. Historic Designation and Residential Market Values. Appraisal Journal, Vol 62, 3, 1994: 396-373. Benson, Virginia O.; Klein, Richard. The Impact of Historic Districting on Property Values. The Appraisal Journal, April, 1998. Ford, Deborah Ann. The Effect of Historic District Designation on Single Family Home Prices. AREUA Journal, Vol 17, 3, 1989: 353-342. Gale, Dennis E. The Impacts of Historic District Designation. Journal of the American Planning Association, Vol 57, 3, 1991: 325-342. Nelson, Arthur C and Talley, Janice. Revitalizaint minority commercial areas through historic district designation. Journal of Urban Affairs, Vol 13, 2, 1991: 221-232. Schaeffer, Peter V. and Millerick, Cecily Ahern. The Impact of Historic District Designation of Property Values: An Empirical Study Economic Development Quarterly, Vol 5, 4, 1991: 223-232. Tiesdell, Steven. Revitalizing historic urban quarters. Boston: Architectural Press, 1996. The Park Place Economist, Volume XII 74