How Wall Street Investors Rescued the Market for Single Family Homes #

Similar documents
Foreclosures Continue to Bring Home Prices Down * FNC releases Q Update of Market Distress and Foreclosure Discount

By several measures, homebuilding made a comeback in 2012 (Figure 6). After falling another 8.6 percent in 2011, single-family

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Housing Recovery: How Far Have We Come? Daniel Hartley and Kyle Fee

James Alm, Robert D. Buschman, and David L. Sjoquist In the wake of the housing market collapse

Shadow inventory in Texas

Volume II Edition I Why This is a Once in a Lifetime Opportunity for Investors

Multifamily Market Commentary December 2015 Single-Family Rental Sector Attracting Institutional Investment

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

things to consider if you are selling your house

State of the Nation s Housing 2008: A Preview

The supply of single-family homes for sale remains

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

things to consider if you are selling your house SPRING 2012

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector

Neighborhood Price Externalities of Foreclosure Rehabilitation: An Examination of the 1 / Neigh 29. Program

Nothing Draws a Crowd Like a Crowd: The Outlook for Home Sales

Residential December 2009

IRVINE, Calif. May 8, 2014

Blackstone-Fueled Single-Family Home Boom Lifts Chicago

Residential January 2009

The Uneven Housing Recovery

CONTENTS. Executive Summary 1. Southern Nevada Economic Situation 2 Household Sector 5 Tourism & Hospitality Industry

Residential September 2010

2008 Midyear Housing Forecast

Residential May Karl L. Guntermann Fred E. Taylor Professor of Real Estate. Adam Nowak Research Associate

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Young-Adult Housing Demand Continues to Slide, But Young Homeowners Experience Vastly Improved Affordability

ROMSPEN REVEST HOMES LP. Reliable Rental Income Plus Significant Capital Appreciation

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

HOUSING MARKET OUTLOOK: SAN LUIS OBISPO, CA AND SURROUNDING AREA

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

U.S. Foreclosure Activity Increases 2 Percent in July Boosted by 6 Percent Increase in Foreclosure Starts

W H O S D R E A M I N G? Homeownership A mong Low Income Families

Volume II Edition III Mid Summer update

ON THE HAZARDS OF INFERRING HOUSING PRICE TRENDS USING MEAN/MEDIAN PRICES

Housing Affordability: Local and National Perspectives

Residential January 2010

ECONOMIC CURRENTS. Vol. 4, Issue 3. THE Introduction SOUTH FLORIDA ECONOMIC QUARTERLY

2013 Update: The Spillover Effects of Foreclosures

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

OBSERVATION. TD Economics IS THE AMERICAN HOUSING REBOUND SUSTAINABLE?

Volume III Edition I 2011 Year end Recap What will 2012 Bring? Financing for Canadians Where are Canadians Buying in the Greater Phoenix area?

Residential March 2010

Residential December 2010

Using Historical Employment Data to Forecast Absorption Rates and Rents in the Apartment Market

Dan Immergluck 1. October 12, 2015

Housing Indicators in Tennessee

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

Changing Geography of Improvement Spending

For the Reno MSA employment has historically been based largely on construction and the leisure and hospitality industry. The construction industry

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Minneapolis St. Paul Residential Real Estate Index

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

A Historical Perspective on Illinois Farmland Sales

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Annual Report On Our National Real Estate Market

Our Housing Market Turns the Corner

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary

2015 First Quarter Market Report

ARLA Members Survey of the Private Rented Sector

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

A M A S T E R S P O L I C Y R E P O R T An Analysis of an Ordinance to Assure the Maintenance, Rehabilitation, Registration, and Monitoring of

Effect of Foreclosures on Nearby Property Values. The effect of real estate foreclosures on nearby property values is well studied by

Multifamily Market Commentary December 2018

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Minneapolis St. Paul Residential Real Estate Index

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Cycle Monitor Real Estate Market Cycles Third Quarter 2017 Analysis

Owner spending on improvements to existing homes also rose over the past year. Benefiting from strengthening house sales, CONSTRUCTION RECOVERY

OVERVIEW OF RECENT/EXPECTED ECONOMIC/ HOUSING MARKET CONDITIONS

Description of IHS Hedonic Data Set and Model Developed for PUMA Area Price Index

Residential October 2009

The impact of the global financial crisis on selected aspects of the local residential property market in Poland

Update of U.S. Residential Real Estate Trends: Including economic data, current sales, new construction,

San Francisco Bay Area to Marin, San Francisco, and San Mateo Counties Housing and Economic Outlook

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

GROWING DIVERSITY OF RENTER HOUSEHOLDS THE STATE OF THE NATION S HOUSING 2012

Addressing the Impact of Housing for Virginia s Economy

Residential July 2010

ARLA Survey of Residential Investment Landlords

Mueller. Real Estate Market Cycle Monitor Third Quarter 2018 Analysis

San Francisco Bay Area to Sonoma County Housing and Economic Outlook

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

Minneapolis St. Paul Residential Real Estate Index

Regression Estimates of Different Land Type Prices and Time Adjustments

Market Trends Generated on 04/24/2018 Page 1 of Alpaca St, South El Monte, CA , Los Angeles County.

Housing and the Economy: Impacts, Forecasts and Challenges

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

REGIONAL. Rental Housing in San Joaquin County

2017 RESIDENTIAL REAL ESTATE MARKET REPORT

Report on Nevada s Housing Market

CONTINUED STRONG DEMAND

REAL ESTATE MARKETING UPDATE

Briefing Book. State of the Housing Market Update San Francisco Mayor s Office of Housing and Community Development

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

Northgate Mall s Effect on Surrounding Property Values

Transcription:

How Wall Street Investors Rescued the Market for Single Family Homes # By Walter D Lima And Paul Schultz Abstract We examine the impact of house purchases by large buy-to-rent investors on the value of nearby properties. Returns on repeat sales of properties within a quarter mile of houses purchased by buy-to-rent investors were significantly greater if the repeat sale concluded after the buy-to-rent purchase. Properties outside the price range normally paid by buy-to-rent investors experienced smaller gains after nearby buyto-rent purchases. Mortgage use increased after the buy-to-rent purchases for nearby properties. Buy-torent investors appear to increase the value of homes in an area by providing liquidity and reducing the local supply of houses. PRELIMINARY DO NOT QUOTE November, 2018 # We are grateful to Francois Cocquemas, Shane Corwin, David Echeverry, Paul Gao, David Hutchison, Alberto Rossi, Sophie Shive, Lin Sun and seminar participants at Florida State University and the University of Notre Dame for comments. All errors are our own. 1

1. Introduction In this paper, we study the impact of purchases of single-family homes by buy-to-rent investors on prices of nearby houses. Following the financial crisis, low house prices and the inability of potential homeowners to get credit provided an opening for institutions to enter the single family home market as buy-to-rent investors. Institutional investors had traditionally shunned the single-family home market, but low prices and the opportunity to take advantage of economies of scale by purchasing many nearby properties brought these new investors into the market. Buy-to-rent investors business model included buying hundreds or thousands of properties in a metropolitan area in foreclosure auctions, renovating them, and renting them out. They are typically organized as real estate investment trusts (REITs). Buy-to-rent investors entered the real estate market to take advantage of what they believed to be an opportunity to buy significantly undervalued assets on a large scale. By 2011, prices of single family homes in some cities had fallen by 30% to 60% from peak 2006 values. In some cities, houses were available for well below replacement cost. Real estate markets seemed to be away from their long-run equilibrium because foreclosures had brought a large number of homes to market and because potential buyers were unable to borrow as a result of losing equity in their previous houses or defaulting on their mortgages. Warren Buffett, on February, 27, 2012 on the CNBC show Squawkbox, said he would like to buy a couple hundred thousand single-family homes if it were practical to do so. Residents of the cities targeted by buy-to-rent investors had concerns about the impact of these investments on their communities. Buy-to-rent investors bring renters into neighborhoods that were formerly comprised of owner-occupied houses. Renters are considered to be undesirable in many neighborhoods and some homeowner s associations forbid owners from leasing property. Renters are less concerned about property values and maintenance than homeowners. Because they are typically shortterm residents, they care less about relations with neighbors than do homeowners. They are less involved in community affairs than owner-occupiers. Another concern about buy-to-rent purchases is that an investor that owns a large number of homes in an area may impose financial risks on nearby homeowners. If the buy-to-rent investor experiences financial difficulties, it may skimp on maintenance or attempt to sell a large number of houses at the same time, putting downward pressure on prices of other nearby houses (see Lambie-Hanson, Li, and Slonkosky (2018)). We show that these fears were groundless. We find that property values increased significantly more after buy-to-rent purchases for nearby properties than for properties located farther away. The results are robust with respect to our definition of nearby properties and the before and after periods surrounding buy-to-rent purchases. 2

Our results are consistent with buy-to-rent investors correctly identifying and purchasing undervalued property. We do not directly calculate the returns that buy-to-rent investors earn on the houses they buy because they sell very few of them during our sample period. Nevertheless, if other properties in a ¼ mile radius appreciate, it is probably a safe assumption that their properties are also appreciating. Price increases for nearby properties after purchases by buy-to-rent investors may also, however, reflect direct effects of the buy-to-rent purchases as well as the investors ability to find undervalued assets. Buy-to-rent investors may increase the value of nearby properties by renovating the houses they buy. In addition, most of the houses purchased by institutional investors were foreclosed. Foreclosed properties in a neighborhood may lead to crime or vandalism. They may be poorly maintained and unsightly eyesores. A second reason why purchases by buy-to-rent investors may increase property values is that they supply liquidity to residential real estate markets. Following the crisis, foreclosures resulted in a glut of properties in many markets. Many homebuyers were unable to get mortgages and were shut out of the market. Buy-to-rent investors provided liquidity and reduced the excess supply of houses. We present some evidence that is consistent with buy-to-rent purchases increasing the value of nearby houses by providing liquidity and reducing the local housing supply. Buy-to-rent investors want middle-class tenants. Hence they buy houses in a narrow price range and avoid both expensive and cheap properties. We show that following buy-to-rent purchases, prices increase more for houses in the price range sought by buy-to-rent investors than for more expensive or cheaper houses. If this is just a reflection of the buy-to-rent investors investment skills, it means that they buy houses in the right place, at the right time, and in the right price range, which just happens to be the price range of their preferred type of rental properties. We also show that mortgage use increases more for properties near buy-to-rent purchases than for distant properties in the months following purchases. Lenders may have been more willing to give credit to homebuyers because buy-to-rent purchases provided information on the value of nearby properties. Alternatively, buy-to-rent investors may have reduced risk to lenders by their willingness to buy foreclosed properties. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the literature on the housing market following the financial crisis and institutional real estate investors. In Section 3 we describe the Zillow data used here. Section 4 describes our tests and results. Section 5 offers conclusions. 2. Institutional investors and the housing market following the crisis 3

Over 2006 2012, house prices fell sharply in many parts of the country. In some cities, houses sold for well below replacement cost. Many homeowners chose to default on mortgages that far exceeded the value of their houses. In June 2012, there were 1.8 million house foreclosures and another 1.3 million homeowners were at least 90 days behind on mortgage payments. Despite low prices and a large supply of available properties, many individuals were unable to buy houses. In some cases, the individuals were left with no equity for down payments after losing money on previous house purchases. In other cases, potential buyers credit ratings were ruined after defaulting on mortgage payments. In addition, mortgage lenders reduced lending and tightened lending standards. Individuals and families who would normally buy homes rented instead. Overall, homeownership fell from 69% in 2006 to 65% in 2013. Edelman (2014) notes that in early 2013, 43 million American households rented housing, as compared to 36.7 million before the crisis. Schnure (2014) observes that the number of families renting single family homes increased from 11.34 million in 2007 to 13.18 million in 2011. The decline was not evenly distributed across the country. Over 2007-2010, single family rental homes increased 48% in Phoenix, 41% in Atlanta, and 36% in Chicago. The decline in homeownership after the crisis was accompanied by home purchases by investors. Allen et al (2018) examine 72,128 single-family home transactions in Miami-Dade County, Florida, between January, 2009 and September, 2013. Investors are the buyers in 34.1% of transactions. Investors in single family homes have traditionally been individuals or partnerships based near the rental properties. Following the crisis, however, institutional buyers began purchasing single family houses as rental properties. Khater (2013) notes that many cities saw sharp declines in real estate inventories in 2012 due to institutional buying activity. Cities that had rapidly increasing institutional buying included Atlanta, Detroit, Las Vegas, Phoenix, Los Angeles, Riverside, and Sacramento. Mills, Molloy, and Zarutskie (2017) propose three explanations for why large institutional investors entered the market for singlefamily homes after the financial crisis. First, the large inventory of homes made it easier for buy-to-rent investors to create geographically concentrated pools of similar homes. Second, tight mortgage financing gave large firms an advantage in competing for houses and spurred demand for rental units. Finally, technological developments like the widespread use of mobile devices and mobile internet connectivity made scattered-site property renovation, maintenance and management more efficient. Institutional investors typically acquire property at low prices. Smith and Liu (2018) examine the prices paid by institutional investors for houses in Atlanta over 2000 2014. They find, that after adjusting for house characteristics and cash purchase and distressed sale discounts, institutional investors purchased houses at significant discounts of 6.3% to 11.8% relative to owner-occupiers. Similarly, Allen et al (2018) show that investors in single-family homes in Miami-Dade County, Florida, purchase at a discount to single-purchase buyers. Discounts are larger for large investors (6 to 28 properties) and 4

medium investors (3 to 5) properties than institutional investors. Part of the reason for the low purchase prices paid by investors is that they are more likely to pay cash than other investors. Even after adjusting for cash payments however, investors pay less than single purchase buyers. Many of the houses purchased by institutional investors during this time were foreclosed. Foreclosed properties in a neighborhood may lead to crime or vandalism. They may be poorly maintained and unsightly eyesores. Gerardi et al (2015) study the impact of foreclosures on nearby properties using 950,234 repeat sale pairs from 15 MSAs. They find that an increase of one house in serious delinquency within 0.1 miles decreases house prices about 1.2%. An increase in one house owned by a bank decreases property values about 1%. Foreclosures resulted in a glut of properties in many markets. Many homebuyers were unable to get mortgages and shut out of the market. Buy-to-rent investors provided liquidity and reduced the excess supply of houses. Anenberg and Kung (2014) examine the impact of foreclosures on prices of nearby homes in Chicago, Phoenix, San Francisco, and Washington DC over 2007-2009 and consider two possible channels for a spillover effect. The first is the negative externalities that vacant houses provide through crime, vandalism, etc. The second, or competitive affect is the effect on house prices of increasing the number of other houses on the market. As a whole, Anenberg and Kung (2014) favor the supply explanation for the house price decline. The limited evidence available to date suggests that house purchases specifically by large buy-torent investors increases nearby house prices. Allen et al (2018) estimate that a 10% increase in purchases by investors (e.g.40% to 50%) in a census tract increases house prices there by 0.20%. 3. Data Our source of data on real estate transactions is Zillow, which in turn obtains them from county deeds. Our data has all real estate transactions in most U.S. counties over 2000 2015. For each transaction, we have the date of the transaction, the identity of the buyer and seller, the price paid for the property, the state, county, city and street address of the property, and the property s latitude and longitude. We have mortgage information including whether the mortgage is a fixed rate mortgage or an ARM, the amount borrowed, term of the mortgage, and the identity of the lender. In most cases we also have annual assessed values of the properties. We restrict our study to seven states: Arizona, California, Florida, Georgia, Illinois, Nevada, and North Carolina. Each of these states is mentioned in prospectuses of large buy-to-rent investors and in articles on the investors that appeared in the popular press. All of these states saw significant activity by buy-to-rent investors over 2010-2015. The sand states of Arizona, California, Florida and Nevada 5

experienced especially large runups in house prices over 2000 2006, and very sharp downturns in house prices afterwards. A. Housing markets before and after the financial crisis There is some variation from city to city in the timing of the housing price peaks, but in general, prices peaked around late 2006 all over the country. The decline in house prices was accompanied by a decline in the liquidity of the housing market. Figure 1 shows the number of home sales, taken from Zillow, for each month over 2003-2015 in Arizona, California, Florida, Illinois, Nevada and North Carolina. 1 The seasonality of home sales is clearly visible here with sales peaking in summer and bottoming out around the turn of the year. Of more interest to us is that in every state, house sales at their peak in 2005 and 2006 were two-to-four times as large as they were in 2008-2009. There was an upward trend in the number of sales over 2010-2015 in Florida and Illinois, but the housing market remained sluggish in every state relative to 2005-2006. Part of the decline in house sales may be due to buyers having difficulty obtaining a mortgage. Following the financial crisis, some lenders conserved capital to build reserves and others instituted more stringent lending standards. Some potential homebuyers had damaged credit ratings following defaults on previous mortgages. Others had little equity for a down payment after losing money on previous house purchases. Figure 2 shows the monthly proportion of homes purchased with mortgages in each state over 2003 2015. In each state, the proportion of houses purchased with mortgages is highest before 2007. In Illinois and North Carolina, the proportion of houses bought with mortgages declines more or less smoothly over 2007-2015. In the other states, the proportion of houses bought with mortgages declined sharply after 2007. In Nevada, about 80% of homes were purchased with mortgages over 2003-2005. In 2008-2009, it was about 35%. In California, about 80% of houses were bought with mortgages over 2003-2005, but less than 50% over 2008-2009. Together, Figures 1 and 2, along with the decline in house prices, suggest a decline in demand for houses and a potential glut in the supply. B. Institutional Investors We focus on the impact of house purchases by eight major buy-to-rent investors: Altisource, American Homes 4 Rent, American Residential Properties, Colony American Homes, Invitation Homes, Progress Residential, Silver Bay Realty Trust and Starwood Waypoint Realty Trust. These investors are among the largest if not the largest buy-to-rent investors and account for a large proportion of the total 1 Several Georgia counties have missing data before 2008, so we do not include Georgia in Figure 1. 6

institutional investment in single-family homes. Purchases by these investors were concentrated in a few states. We examine purchases in the states of Arizona, California, Florida, Georgia, Illinois, North Carolina, and Nevada. These investors purchased additional houses in other states, including Tennessee, Indiana, and Ohio, but the bulk of their purchases were in the seven states that we examine. Prospectuses and company press releases suggest that all of these buy-to-rent investors have a similar business model. They are organized as real estate investment trusts (REITs). Most of their houses are purchased for cash at foreclosure auctions at a discount to prices of houses that are not in foreclosure. They are unable to conduct interior inspections before purchase, and rely on computer models to determine which houses to buy and how much to pay. They typically spend $20,000 to $25,000 to renovate properties before renting them out. They attempt to take advantage of economies of scale by purchasing large numbers of houses in a metropolitan area. Buy-to-rent investors prefer to rent to middle class families. Their preferred purchase is a three-bedroom, two-bathroom house in a good school district. All of these buy-to-rent investors entered real estate markets in the same cities at about the same time. Single family homes appeared to be a very good investment to many value investors. Table 1 reports the number of house purchases that we identify in the Zillow data for each of these investors in each state. In total, they purchased over 100,000 homes. The largest number, 39,770 were in Florida. Invitation Homes, a subsidiary of Blackstone, was the most active buyer with 29,384 house purchases. There is some specialization by investors in different states. For example, almost half of American Residential Properties purchases are in Arizona. For the most part though, investors spread their purchases across all seven states. Figure 3 depicts the number of purchases by all of the Wall Street investors combined by month for four counties with a large number of purchases: Maricopa County, Arizona (Phoenix), Clark County, Nevada (Las Vegas), Broward County Florida, and Los Angeles County, California. In each case, the number of purchases was particularly large during the second half of 2013. In the case of Los Angeles County, purchases were high in 2012, and for Broward County, Florida and Clark County, Nevada, heavy buying continued well into 2014. For the most part though, investor activity is roughly synchronous across locations. 4. Results A. Institutional Purchases and Prices of Nearby Houses We identify bundles of purchases by institutional buyers in the following way. Starting with all institutional purchases in a state within a month, we identify the pair of homes that were located closest to one another. Distances are straight-line distances calculated from the properties latitude and longitude. If the pair were within ½ mile of each other, we identify them as a bundle. We define the center of the 7

bundle as the average latitude and longitude of the houses in the bundle. With two houses, this means that each is within ¼ mile of the bundle center. We then go through the set of all institutional purchases a second time and pick out the next closest pair of houses. If the pair is within ½ mile of each other this is a second bundle. If instead, the closest pair is a new house and the center of the previous bundle, the new house is added to the bundle, and the new center is the average of the latitudes and longitudes of the three houses that make up the bundle. We continue this process until all other houses purchased by institutional buyers are more than ½ mile from existing bundles or other institutional house purchases. Houses that are more than ½ mile from any others are treated as bundles by themselves. Bundles are small. About 79% are one house, and about 94% are one or two houses. A number, however, include over 10 houses. We do not require that all houses in a bundle be purchased by the same buy-to-rent investor. We then find all repeat sales of houses within ¼ of a mile of the center of each bundle for which the second sale took place in the 12 months before or after the institutional purchases. As a control, we also find all repeat sales of houses in the same state between 50 and 75 miles away from the center of the bundle. These properties are also at least 50 miles from the center of any other bundle. Using all repeat sales, we estimate the following regression llll PP 2 = γγ PP BBBBBBBBBBBB,BBBBBBBBBBBBBB + αα 1 DD 1 + αα < 2DD 1 4 MMMMMMMM AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA + αα 3 DD 1 DD < 4 MMMMMMMM AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA + εε ii (1) Where P 2 is the price of the house in the second transaction, P 1 is the house price in the first transaction, γ,bundlebuyyear is a fixed effect for the combination of the institutional buy bundle and the purchase year for the first trade in the round trip. D <1/4Mileis a dummy variable that is one if the property is no more than ¼ miles from the center of the bundle, D AfterInst.Buy is a dummy variable that is one if the second transaction in the repeat sale took place in the 12 months following the institutional purchases in the bundle, and zero if the transaction took place in the 12 months before the institutional purchases. Note that with the fixed effects we control for the location of the house and the year of the first transaction in the repeat sale. Hence the coefficient of D AfterInst.Buy reflects the difference in real estate returns of houses that were bought around the same time but sold before and after the institutional purchases, while the coefficient on the product of D <1/4Mile and D AfterInst.Buy is the additional difference in real estate returns for houses that were bought around the same time but sold before and after the institutional purchases and were located near the center of the bundle. We first estimate (1) using transactions from all seven states. Results are reported in Panel A of Table 2. Regression (1) reports results when we do not cluster standard errors on the repeat sale and include every repeat sale. There are a total of 3,194,931 observations in this regression and 312,855 fixed effects for bundles of institutional purchases. So, on average, about ten sales take place within a year of institutional bundle purchases. The intercept coefficient is 0.0109. In Stata, when fixed effects are used, 8

the intercept is the average fixed effect. In this case it indicates that home sellers made e 0.0109 = 1.1% on their houses if they sold before the institutional purchases. The coefficient on D <1/4Mile is -0.2421, so home sellers who had properties close to the future buy-to-rent investor purchase lost e 0.0109-0.2421 1 = 20.6% when they sold. This is not surprising. Buy-to-rent investors bought into areas with depressed house prices. Our sample consists of house sales that took place in 2010 2015, and sellers typically purchased their houses before the collapse of real estate prices in 2007-2009. The coefficient on the dummy variable for after institutional purchases is -0.0009 with a t-statistic of -0.52. Prices for houses located 50 to 75 miles from the buy-to-rent bundle did not increase in value after the buy-to-rent purchase. The coefficient on the interaction between being close to a buy-to-rent bundle and selling after the institution purchased is 0.1240 with a t-statistic of 34.53. House prices did increase significantly after buy-to-rent institutional investors bought houses, but only for houses near their purchases. In the regression reported in the second column, we cluster standard errors on the repeat sales. By doing this, we acknowledge that the same repeat sale, when used with different bundles of institutional purchases in different months, does not provide independent observations. In this regression we also exclude repeat sales with the largest and smallest 1% of returns. Very large returns could reflect expensive property improvements. Very small returns may occur if the second transaction in a repeat sale is not an arm s length transaction. A house could be sold, for example, to a son or daughter. Very large or small returns could also be due to data errors. This second regression, with standard errors clustered on the repeat sale and outliers omitted will be the base case regression used for individual states and other applications. Coefficient estimates for the second regressions are very similar to the coefficient estimates in the first regression. Exclusion of outliers has little effect on the estimated impact of institutional purchases on nearby property prices. Clustering of standard errors does reduce t-statistics, but coefficients remain statistically significant, particularly on the dummy variable for being within a ¼ mile of a buy-to-rent bundle, and the interaction between that dummy variable and the dummy for after the buy-to-rent investor purchased property. Again, prices increase for nearby properties, and only nearby properties, after buy-torent investors purchase houses. For the third regression, we continue to omit outliers and cluster standard errors on the repeat sale. This time though, we use six months, rather than one year for the before and after period. Results are basically unchanged, with the coefficient on the interaction between the dummy variable for after institutional purchases and the dummy variable for being within ¼ of the buy-to-rent property decreasing from 0.0969 to 0.0772. This is not a statistically significant difference. The fourth regression includes only repeat sales of houses that were within 1/10 of a mile of a bundle of institutional purchases, and that occurred with one year before or after the institutional 9

purchases. This has a small impact on the coefficient on the interaction between being close to the buy-torent bundle and selling after the bundle is purchased, raising it from 0.0969 in the second regression to 0.1054. The impact of institutional purchases on houses within 1/10 of a mile is just slightly larger than the impact on houses within ¼ of a mile. Finally, the fifth regression includes only round trips within 1/10 of a mile of the cluster of institutional purchases in which the last trade took place within six months of the purchases. The coefficient on the interaction between being close to a buy-to-rent bundle and selling after the buy-to-rent purchase is 0.0842. Results across these regressions seem to indicate that being closer to the center of a bundle has a larger impact on prices, and as does using a longer before and after period. As a whole, Panel A demonstrates that our results are robust to changes in methodology. Following a purchase by a buy-to-rent investor, prices increase more for nearby houses than for distant houses. That is true whether outliers are included or not, whether nearby is defined as 1/10 mile or ¼ mile, and whether the before and after period is six months or one year. Panel B provides evidence on the impact of buy-to-rent purchases for each of the individual states. The individual state regressions are the same as the second regression from Panel A. That is, outliers are omitted, standard errors are clustered on the repeat sale, the before and after period is one year, and repeat sales are near to the buy-to-rent bundle if they are within ¼ mile. For Arizona, California, Florida, Nevada and Illinois, results are similar to the results for all states combined. The coefficient on the dummy variable for being close to the dummy is negative and statistically significant. Before the buyto-rent investors moved in, prices had fallen more for houses near where they bought than for houses farther away. After the buy-to-rent investors purchased, prices of nearby houses increased by more than those of houses farther away. Results for Georgia and North Carolina are different. Estimates of α 2 coefficients indicate that buy-to-rent investors are not buying into areas that had experienced greater price declines. Prices of houses near the buy-to-rent purchases do not increase more than do distant houses after the buy-to-rent investors purchase homes. Put another way, there was a big decline in prices for houses in the areas where buy-to-rent investors entered the market and a big recovery but only for the states that were hit hard by the collapse of house prices in 2007-2008. As a robustness test, we form bundles of purchases by buy-to-rent investors based on purchases within a quarter rather than purchases within a month. We then rerun the second regression of Panel A for all states and for each individual state. We then compare returns from repeat sales that were concluded in the year before the buy-to-rent purchase with returns from repeat sales that were completed in the following year for properties within ¼ mile of the bundle and for properties 50 to 75 miles away. We do not include repeat sales that were completed in the same quarter as the buy-to-rent bundle was purchased. 10

Results are in Panel C. If anything, results are stronger than in Panels A & B. For Georgia, the coefficient on the interaction between after the buy-to-rent purchase and close to the bundle is now positive and significant. When all states are combined, the coefficient on the interaction between after the buy-to-rent purchase and close to the bundle is larger as is the coefficient s t-statistic. A potential concern is that the increase in house prices following institutional purchases may come from the purchases of just one investor. As a robustness check, we regress returns for repeat sales that occurred with ¼ mile of a buy-to-rent purchase bundle on a dummy variable for after the buy-to-rent investor purchased. As before, regressions have fixed effects for each combination of purchase year and purchase bundle. We run this regression first using all purchases by buy-to-rent investors, and then omitting the purchases of one institution at a time. These regressions are reported in Panel D. Omitting the transactions of one buyer has little effect on the results. The coefficient on the dummy variable for after an institutional purchase ranges from 0.0977 when Colony Homes is omitted to 10.86% when American Homes 4 Rent is not included. The results in Table 2 show clearly that prices of nearby houses rose after purchases by buy-torent investors. Property owners concerns about potential detrimental effects of renters moving into their neighborhood seem less important than the benefits of purchases by buy-to-rent investors. There are several possible reasons why prices of nearby homes increase following institutional purchases. First, the institutions may simply be smart investors. They may be purchasing in anticipation of house prices rising in that area in the near future. Second, institutional investor purchases may increase the value of nearby home by eliminating dis-amenities or negative externalities. Wall Street investors were buying up properties after sharp declines in real estate prices. In many cases the houses were foreclosed or payments were delinquent. In these circumstances, owners may cut back on maintenance, potentially making houses eyesores for the neighborhood. Vacant houses may attract crime, vandalism, or squatters. Purchase of these houses by institutional investors may increase the value of nearby properties by eliminating negative externalities. Finally, institutional purchases may increase the value of nearby homes by reducing the supply of houses for sale in the city. The runup in houses prices before the financial crisis led to an increase in supply through new construction. After prices declined, some potential homeowners were unable to purchase houses as a result of losing equity in their house or more stringent mortgage standards. The resulting glut of houses depressed real estate prices. Institutional investors bought, in some cases, hundreds of homes per month in a city, thereby sharply reducing supply. B. Buy-to-Rent Purchases and Mortgage Lending 11

Without some exogenous factor that causes a change in the number of purchases by institutional investors, it is difficult to distinguish the impact of institutional purchases of prices on nearby houses from institutional investors successful forecasting of a rise in real estate prices. If buy-to-rent investors improve the housing market in an area, either by eliminating dis-amenities associated with vacant or foreclosed homes or by reducing the supply of houses, banks might become less reluctant to lend to homebuyers in the area. To test this, we estimate the regression of equation (1). This time, rather than using the return on the round trip transaction as the dependent variable, we use an indicator variable for the use of a mortgage to buy the house. That is, DD MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM = γγ BBBBBBBBBBBB,BBBBBBBBBBBBBB + αα 1 DD 1 + αα < 2DD 4 MMMMMMMM AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA + αα 3 DD 1 DD < 4 MMMMMMMM AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA + εε ii (2) As before, each observation is sale of a property that is close to a buy-to-rent investor s bundle of purchases or distant from that bundle. Close is defined as within ¼ mile of the center of the bundle, while distant is 50 to 75 miles away. The transaction must occur within within the 12 months prior to the acquisition of property by the buy-to-rent investor, or in the 12 months afterwards. Fixed effects are included for each bundle. Standard errors are clustered on the property sales. Results are shown in Table 3. Panel A provides regression results when transactions from all states are included. The first regression uses ¼ mile as the distance for a close property and uses transactions from one year before and one year after the buy-to-rent purchases. The intercept coefficient is 0.3415, indicating that 34.15% of house purchases 50-75 miles away from the buy-to-rent bundle used mortgages before the buy-to-rent purchase. The proportion of purchases within ¼ mile of the buy-to-rent bundle that occurred before the buy-to-rent purchase that used a mortgage was lower by 1.48%. Regression (1) indicates that after the buy-to-rent purchase, the proportion of purchases that used mortgages increased by 1.15% and an additional 3.44% for a total of 4.59% for nearby properties. Mortgage use increased much more for properties that were close to the buy-to-rent bundle than for distant properties. Following buy-to-rent purchases, lenders become more willing to lend to buyers purchasing property near the buy-to-rent bundle. It is possible that lenders believe that buy-to-rent investors are eliminating an excess supply of houses in the area, and that a foreclosure would be easier to dispose of if the borrower defaulted. It is also possible that lenders believe the buy-to-rent investor would be willing to purchase the property if the borrower defaulted. Alternatively, the increase in mortgages could reflect a change in the house buyers. Individuals who invest in houses are less likely to use mortgages than homebuyers who intend to live in the properties. Perhaps, more of the houses are being bought by buyers who will live in them. In regression (2) and the remaining regressions in Panel A, standard errors are clustered on the transactions. This reduces t-statistics, but the coefficient on the interaction between a property being 12

located near the buy-to-rent bundle and the transaction occurring after the buy to rent purchase remains positive and highly significant in each regression. Mortgages are more likely to be used for houses near the buy-to-rent purchases after the purchase takes place. In regression (4), close to the bundle is defined as being with 1/10 of a mile rather than ¼ mile. This is roughly one city block. Now the coefficient on the dummy for being located close to the bundle is a statistically significant -0.0276. Prior to the buy-to-rent purchase mortgages were less common for nearby properties. The coefficient on the interaction between close to the bundle and after the bundle purchase increases to 0.0418 with a t-statistic of 4.10. Buy-to-rent purchases seem to have a particularly large effect on the likelihood of using a mortgage to purchase very close properties. Panel B reports regression estimates for each individual state. Intercepts and other coefficients vary substantially across states, suggesting that a lot of information may be lost by putting all states into the same regression. In the individual state regressions, with the exception of North Carolina, the coefficient on the interaction between close to the buy-to-rent bundle and after the buy-to-rent purchase is positive, larger than in the regression with all states, and significant at the 1% level. Mortgage use increased for properties near buy-to-rent purchases after the purchases occurred. C. Why do Prices Increase Following Buy-to-Rent Purchases? There are three explanations for our finding that prices of nearby houses increase after buy-to-rent purchases. First, it is possible that buy-to-rent investors are skilled investors who correctly forecasted rising house prices. Second, it is possible that purchases by buy-to-rent investors increase the value of nearby properties by reducing externalities from foreclosed or distressed properties. Most of the houses bought by buy-to-rent investors were in foreclosure. Foreclosed homes tend to be poorly maintained and may, in addition to being unsightly, attract crime and vandalism. Finally, purchases by buy-to-rent investors provide liquidity to the real estate market and reduced the excessive supply of houses available in certain cities after the financial crisis. These explanations are not mutually exclusive and all may be true to some degree. In this section we explore the question of which of these explanations seems most important. We do not provide tests that allow us to cleanly reject one or more of the hypotheses. Wall Street investors generally buy houses in price ranges that allow them to profitably rent to middle class tenants. Expensive houses are difficult to rent. Cheap houses require more maintenance and have tenants who are more likely to miss payments. Purchases by Wall Street investors would reduce supply for houses in the price range in which they buy, but not for either very cheap or very expensive houses. The housing market is not perfectly segmented by price, but nonetheless we would not expect 13

returns of cheap or expensive houses to be affected as much by buy-to-rent purchases as returns of houses in the price range favored by these investors. For each state, we calculate the distribution of purchase prices paid by Wall Street investors over 2010-2015. Results are shown in Panel A of Table 4. The distribution of prices across all states is shown in the first row. The median price is $144,184, while the 5 th percentile price if $65,000 and the 95 th percentile price is $305,000. Distributions of prices for each individual state are presented in the following rows. Prices are generally higher in California and lower in Georgia. The range of prices in individual states is usually narrower than the distribution across all states. For comparison purposes, Panel B provides the distribution of prices in all transactions over 2010 2015. For all states together, and for the individual states, the dispersion of prices in all transactions exceeds the dispersion of prices paid by buy-to-rent investors. This confirms that buy-to-rent investors purchase houses in a specific segment of the market, in a price range that appeals to middle-class renters. To see if returns for properties that are outside of the price range of buy-to-rent investors are affected by buy-to-rent purchases, we run the following regression using repeat sales of properties within ½ mile of the center of a bundle of houses purchased by an investor. llll PP 2 PP 1 = γγ IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII,BBBBBBBBBBBBBB + αα 1 PP 1<5tth PPPPPP + αα 2 PP 1>95tth PPPPPPPPPPPPPPPPPPPP + αα 3 DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA.BBBBBB + αα 4 PP 1<5tth PPPPPP DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA + PP 1>95tth PPPPPP DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA.BBBBBB + εε ii (3) Where γ InstHouse,BuyYear is a fixed effect for the buy-to-rent purchase bundle and the purchase year of the repeat sale property, P 1< 5th Pct is a dummy variable if the first price in the repeat sale was less than the 5 th percentile of purchase prices for buy-to-rent investors, P 1> 95th Pct is a dummy variable if the first price in the repeat sale was greater than the 95 th percentile of purchase prices for buy-to-rent investors, and D AfterInstBuy is a dummy variable that is one if the second transaction in the repeat purchase took place after the purchase by the buy-to-rent investor. By using ½ mile rather than ¼ mile we are better able to include nearby properties that sold for very different prices than the properties purchased by buy-to-rent investors. We do not include more distant properties. We include only repeat sales in which the second sale occurred within 12 months of the purchase of the cluster of houses. Regression estimates are provided in Table 5. The first column provides the regression estimate when observations from all states are included. As before, we use fixed effects for each combination of purchase bundle and year of the first transaction in the repeat sale. Standard errors are clustered by the repeat sale. The intercept for the regression is - 0.2257, indicating that on average, homeowners who lived within ½ mile of a buy-to-rent bundle and sold in the 12 months before the bundle purchase suffered significant losses. The coefficient on the dummy variable for cheap properties is 0.5754, suggesting that these homeowners sold property for significant 14

gains in the year before the bundle purchase. It is possible though, that owners of cheap property spent more on repairs and renovations than other homeowners, and the returns could therefore be exaggerated. The coefficient on the dummy variable for expensive properties is -0.0401. Returns on these properties were particularly low if sold before investors purchased the nearby bundle of homes. Of course, our main concern is the impact of Wall Street investors purchases on prices of nearby homes. The coefficient on the dummy variable for a second sale that took place after the investor purchase is 0.1141. Prices of nearby homes were significantly higher in the year after the purchase of houses by Wall Street investors. More interesting is that the dummy variables for cheap and expensive houses are both negative. The coefficient on the cheap house after the bundle purchase is -0.0376, with a t-statistic of -7.22. The coefficient on the interaction between after the institution purchase and an expensive house is -0.0174 with a t-statistic of -5.53. Houses outside the price range purchased by Wall Street investors gained less after the investor purchases. Externalities from nearby vacant houses should affect the values of all nearby homes, regardless of their value. To the extent that the home market is segmented by price, this is consistent with price appreciation being a result of investors removing the excess supply of houses from the market. Regressions for individual states are shown in the remaining columns. The coefficients on the interaction between cheap houses and after the investor purchase are negative for every state except Georgia, and are significant at the 5% level for Florida, North Carolina, and Nevada. The coefficients on the interaction between expensive houses and transactions after the Wall Street investor purchase are negative for all states, and significant at the 5% level for Arizona, California, Florida, Illinois and Nevada. Investor purchases had less impact on the returns to selling nearby houses outside their price range, than on the returns of houses with similar prices. Results in Table 5 seem most consistent with the explanation that purchases by buy-to-rent investors increased house prices by providing liquidity, or, equivalently, by reducing an excess supply of houses. If the housing market is at least somewhat segmented by price, we would expect a reduction in the supply of houses to have the biggest impact on similarly-priced houses. The results don t seem as consistent with the reducing externalities explanation. If nearby house prices increase after buy-to-rent purchases because of a reduction in negative externalities, we might expect returns on cheaper and more expensive houses to be similar to returns on houses in the buy-to-rent price range. Indeed, it would not be surprising if expensive houses were even more affected by eliminating the negative externalities from foreclosed houses. The idea that buy-to-rent investors are superior investors seems implausible as a complete explanation for the results of Table 5. It requires that buy-to-rent investors pick houses in the right neighborhoods, at the right time, and in the right price range, which just happens to be the price range they think is best for rentals. 15

Similarly, land may not be a good substitute for the houses purchased by buy-to-rent investors. Hence restricting the supply of houses in an area may not have much effect on local land prices. To test this, we run the following regression using repeat sales of both land and houses that occurred with ¼ mile and within one year of a purchase by a buy-to-rent investor llll PP 2 = γγ PP IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII,BBBBBBBBBBBBBB + DD LLLLLLLL + DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA.BBBBBB + DD LLLLLLLL DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA.BBBBBB + εε ii. (6) 1 Regression results are reported in Table 6 for all states together and for each state separately. Coefficients on the dummy variable for land are positive and significant. Landowners with property near a bundle bought by a buy-to-rent investor made money on average if they sold before the buy-to-rent purchase. The coefficient on the interaction between land and a sale after the buy-to-rent purchase is negative and significant for all states and for Arizona, Florida, and Georgia. Values of nearby land increased when buy-to-rent investors bought property, but not by as much as house prices increased. This finding is also consistent with prices increasing as a result of buy-to-rent purchases reducing supply. To the extent that the land and house markets are segmented, purchases of houses should affect the supply, and thus prices of houses, but not of land. This also seems inconsistent with the explanation that buy-torent investors are superior investors who correctly forecast returns. Because land represents a fixed location but structures can be built, land is usually the high beta asset with respect to local real estate prices. For the superior investor explanation to hold, it is not enough that buy-to-rent investors forecast local real estate returns. They also have to forecast the unusual result that house price increases exceed land price increases. If institutional investor purchases of houses raised the value of other homes as a result of eliminating externalities, we would expect the impact to be greater for nearby homes. On the other hand, if institutional investor purchases raised property values by restricting the supply of properties, we would expect institutional investor purchases to affect property values over a wider area. To test this we use a difference-in-difference approach. We consider the impact of a purchase by a buy-to-rent investor on prices of properties within ¼ mile of a bundle of institutional purchases, and properties five to ten miles away rather than 50 to 75 miles away. The distant properties are not included if they are within five miles of any other buy-to-rent purchase cluster. Properties that are five to ten miles away will be in the same metropolitan area, and people moving into that area would likely consider houses near the buy-to-rent bundle and properties five to ten miles away as close substitutes. So, a reduction in the supply of houses from buy-to-rent purchases would likely affect the value of both close properties and those that are five to ten miles away. On the other hand, eliminating the externalities associated with vacant or foreclosed properties is likely to affect the prices of houses with a ¼ mile, but less likely to affect the prices of houses five to ten miles away. We estimate the following regression 16

llll PP 2 PP 1 = γγ IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII,BBBBBBBBBBBBBB + DD <.25 MMMMMMMMMM + DD AAAAAAAAAAIIIIIIII.BBBBBB + DD <.25 MMMMMMMMMM DD AAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAAA.BBBBBB + εε ii (3) As before, P 2 is the price of the house in the second transaction, P 1 is the house price in the first transaction, γ InstHouse,BuyYear is a fixed effect for the combination of the institutional buy bundle and the purchase year for the first trade in the round trip. D AfterInst.Buy is a dummy variable that is one if the second transaction in the repeat sale took place in the 12 months following the institutional purchases in the bundle, and zero if the transaction took place in the 12 months before the institutional purchases. D <.25Miles is a dummy variable that takes a value of one if the property is within ¼ miles of the institutional purchase bundle. Results are presented in Table 7, with Panel A reporting results when properties in all states are included. In the first regression, the number of observations is 1,778,636. There are 258,018 purchase year-bundle fixed effects, so there are an average of about seven repeat sales for each. Regression (1) uses all repeat sales and does not cluster standard errors. The intercept is -0.0077 and the coefficient on the dummy variable for being close to the bundle of institutional properties is -0.1269. Homeowners who were located five to ten miles from the institutional bundles lost a little when they sold houses before the institutional purchase, but homeowners who were located within ¼ of a mile experienced significant additional losses if they sold before the institutional purchase. The coefficient on the dummy variable for the period after the institutional purchase is 0.0890, suggesting that returns were about 9% greater for the homeowners who sold after the institutional purchase than for the homeowners who sold before. That is, prices increased in a broad area around the institutional purchases, not just within ¼ mile. Houses located several miles away in the same metropolitan area are likely to be good substitutes for many buyers. The externalities associated with vacant houses seem unlikely to extend to five miles from the property. Hence, this finding is consistent with house prices increasing as a result of buy-to-rent investors reducing supply. The coefficient on the interaction of the dummy variables for a sale after the institutional purchase and a location close to the institutional bundle is 0.0238. While house prices in the area rose after an institutional purchase, they rose about 2.4% more for houses close to the bundle of institution purchased properties. The second regression is like the first, but omits the observations in which the return is in the top or bottom 1%. Standard errors are also clustered by the repeat sale. Results are very similar. Property prices increased after institutional purchases for properties within a ¼ mile of the institutional purchases and also properties that were located five to ten miles away. Price increases were about 2.5% larger for the nearby properties. This suggests a smaller but significant effect of externalities on prices. 17