Naked Exclusion with Minimum-Share Requirements

Similar documents
Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Oligopoly Theory (6) Endogenous Timing in Oligopoly

Oligopoly Theory (8) Product Differentiation and Spatial Competition

Rent economic rent contract rent Ricardian Theory of Rent:

The Optimal Taxation of Polluters in Non-Competitive Markets: Does Regulatory Sequence Matter? SPPA Working Paper. May 21, 2008

Lecture 18 Land use externalities and the Coase theorem

Game theory. Análisis Económico de la Empresa. M. En C. Eduardo Bustos Farías 1

A NOTE ON AD VALOREM AND PER UNIT TAXATION IN AN OLIGOPOLY MODEL

Efficient Delegation by an Informed Principal 1

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Incentives for Spatially Coordinated Land Conservation: A Conditional Agglomeration Bonus

On the Disutility and Discounting of Imprisonment and the Theory of Deterrence

Comparing Specific and Ad Valorem Taxes under Price-inelastic Demand with Quality Differentiation

Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach

The Ethics and Economics of Private Property

Negative Gearing and Welfare: A Quantitative Study of the Australian Housing Market

Economics. Oligopoly. Measuring Market Concentration. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: N. Gregory Mankiw

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF SOUTH CAROLINA COLUMBIA DIVISION

Oligopoly. Introduction: Between Monopoly and Competition. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: Two extremes

Got too Much Space? Sublease it.

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights.

Oligopoly. Introduction: Between Monopoly and Competition. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: Two extremes

Chapter 5 Topics in the Economics of Property Law

TRUST, INDEMNITY AND SECURITY AGREEMENT WITH DEPOSIT OF FUNDS TO PROTECT AND SECURE AGAINST EXCEPTIONS TO TITLE

ECON 522- SECTION 4- INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, FUGITIVE PROP- 1. Intellectual Property. 2. Adverse Possession. 3. Fugitive Property

A Welfare Analysis of Conservation Easement Tax Credits

Single Payments of the CAP: Where Do the Rents Go?

Percentage Leases and the Advantages of Regional Malls

1. Price UNLOCKING HOME SALES. Is the property priced lower than homes a buyer would consider comparable?

Optimal Penalties in Contracts

Entry and Inefficiency in the Real Estate Brokerage Industry

Housing Transfer Taxes and Household Mobility: Distortion on the Housing or Labour Market? Christian Hilber and Teemu Lyytikäinen

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

An Evaluation of Ad valorem and Unit Taxes on Casino Gaming

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

Accounting for Amalgamations

The dynamics of city formation: finance and governance*

THE REAL ESTATE INDUSTRY 3 PERSPECTIVES

Gregory W. Huffman. Working Paper No. 01-W22. September 2001 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235

Solutions to Questions

GENERAL TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF PURCHASE

Reasons For Rejecting The LIDL Site Plan March 29, 2017

Damage Measures for Inadvertant Breach of Contract

Land Acquisition for Industrialization and Compensation of Displaced Farmers

Accounting for Amalgamations

CONTRACTS THREE HOURS. THIS IS A CLOSED-BOOK EXAM.

Affordable Housing Policy. Economics 312 Martin Farnham

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

Waiting for Affordable Housing in NYC

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 4: Government intervention in the housing market: Who wins, who loses?

Land Acquisition for Industrialization and Compensation of Displaced Farmers

Tenants Rights in Foreclosure 1

The Value of Real Estate

Comment on the Exposure Draft Leases

NEW APPROACHES TO THE THEORY OF RENTAL CONTRACTS IN AGRICULTURE. Clive Bell and Pinhas Zusman

Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis

EXCLUSIVITY OR OPTION AGREEMENT SALE OF [ NAME OF PROPERTY] DATED THE [ ] DAY OF [ MONTH ] relating to. between [PARTY 1] and

Housing Assignment with Restrictions: Theory and Evidence from Stanford University s Campus

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

ASSURANCE AND ACCOUNTING ASPE - IFRS: A Comparison Investment Property

An Architect s View of Product Warranties. Albuquerque CSI Continuing Education Conference Paul Simonsen, FCSI, NCARB, CCS, CCCA, LEED AP

Interlinkage, limited liability and strategic interaction

The Impact of Rent Controls in Non-Walrasian Markets: An Agent-Based Modeling Approach

INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY IN LANDHOLDING DISTRIBUTION OF RURAL BANGLADESH

Patent licensing with Bertrand competitors

OUR GOVERNMENT AT WORK: JUSTICE DEPARTMENT SUES NAR. By John Dolgetta, Associate of The Law Firm of Edward I. Sumber, P.C.

LEASES AND OTHER TRANSFERABLE CONTRACTS

Residential Construction in Farmland Preservation Zoning Districts

WEEK 9 Investment Property IAS 40

Housing Costs and Policies

Racial Prejudice in a Search Model of the Urban Housing Market: Lewis Team Notes

Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property

Accurate Valuation in the Absence of Markets

5. Co-Operative Societies

CB-5 INCLUSIONARY AIR RIGHTS

Land Acquisition for Industrialization and Compensation of Displaced Farmers

An Auction Mechanism for the Optimal Provision of Ecosystem Services under Climate Change

Testing Cost Inefficiency under Free Entry in the Real Estate Brokerage Industry

Whether a rent-to-own (RTO) contract for a consumer good is a true lease or a conditional sales contract for Federal income tax purposes.

Aktuelle regnskapsmessige problemstillinger fra et selskaps ståsted. KRISTIANSAND SYMPOSIUM 15 Juni 2010 Lars Ragnar Vigdel

Addressing Additionality in REDD Contracts when Formal Enforcement is Absent Selected Paper No. 712

EITF Issue No EITF Issue No Working Group Report No. 1, p. 1

Principles and Background Terry Kastens

Top Leasing Tips for Corporate Space Tenants

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 04-06

Part Six The Transformation of Surplus Profit into Ground-Rent

Pricing. Selection of Methods / Comparables Examples/ Case studies. Sanjay Kapadia

License award process for 3G and 2G

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

Houses Across Time and Space

1 February FNB House Price Index - Real and Nominal Growth

An advisory leaflet for landlords and tenants

An intangible asset is an identifiable non-monetary asset without physical substance.

THE COMPETITION TRIBUNAL. IN THE MATTER OF the Competition Act, R.S.C. 1985, c. C-34, as amended;

Legal Q & A. Unpaid Water & Sewer Bills: What Can and Cannot Be Done? By Roger Huebner, General Counsel, IML and Jerry Zarley, Paralegal, IML

Fulfilment of the contract depends on the use of an identified asset; and

Social rents policy: choices and trade-offs

Policy Coordination in an Oligopolistic Housing Market

ISSUE 1 Fourth Quarter, REALTORS Commercial Alliance Series HOT TOPICS ANSWERS TO CURRENT BUSINESS ISSUES TENANTS-IN-COMMON INTERESTS

Transcription:

Naked Exclusion with Minimum-Share Requirements Zhijun Chen and Greg Shaffer Ecole Polytechnique and University of Auckland University of Rochester February 2011

Introduction minimum-share requirements in contracts: what are they? a contract between a buyer and a seller in which the buyer agrees to give the seller some minimum share of its total purchases. you agree to buy at least s% of your purchases from me. exclusive dealing is a special case (in an exclusive-dealing arrangement, you agree not to buy from anyone else besides me). effi ciency rationales/competitive concerns maybe induce more investment, greater service provision but... might also weaken competitors by foreclosing sales

Introduction minimum-share requirements in contracts: what are they? a contract between a buyer and a seller in which the buyer agrees to give the seller some minimum share of its total purchases. you agree to buy at least s% of your purchases from me. exclusive dealing is a special case (in an exclusive-dealing arrangement, you agree not to buy from anyone else besides me). effi ciency rationales/competitive concerns maybe induce more investment, greater service provision but... might also weaken competitors by foreclosing sales

Competition policy how should competition policy treat minimum-share requirements? exclusive dealing is treated under a rule of reason (could be good, could be bad, facts need to be considered) for other share requirements... one might be tempted to think of them as a weaker versions of exclusive dealing (if a contract with exclusive dealing would be allowed, then so would contracts with a smaller share requirement; but the latter might be permissable even if ED would not) this begs the question why would a seller who wants to exclude its rival offer buyers contracts that specify less than a 100% share?

Competition policy how should competition policy treat minimum-share requirements? exclusive dealing is treated under a rule of reason (could be good, could be bad, facts need to be considered) for other share requirements... one might be tempted to think of them as a weaker versions of exclusive dealing (if a contract with exclusive dealing would be allowed, then so would contracts with a smaller share requirement; but the latter might be permissable even if ED would not) this begs the question why would a seller who wants to exclude its rival offer buyers contracts that specify less than a 100% share?

Competition policy how should competition policy treat minimum-share requirements? exclusive dealing is treated under a rule of reason (could be good, could be bad, facts need to be considered) for other share requirements... one might be tempted to think of them as a weaker versions of exclusive dealing (if a contract with exclusive dealing would be allowed, then so would contracts with a smaller share requirement; but the latter might be permissable even if ED would not) this begs the question why would a seller who wants to exclude its rival offer buyers contracts that specify less than a 100% share?

Two main themes of today s talk a seller may prefer to offer partial exclusionary contracts (and by that I mean contracts that specify minimum-share requirements of less than 100%) over fully exclusionary contracts even when the seller s intent is to nakedly exclude. partial exclusionary contracts can be more anticompetitive than fully exclusionary contracts at least in some cases.

Two main themes of today s talk a seller may prefer to offer partial exclusionary contracts (and by that I mean contracts that specify minimum-share requirements of less than 100%) over fully exclusionary contracts even when the seller s intent is to nakedly exclude. partial exclusionary contracts can be more anticompetitive than fully exclusionary contracts at least in some cases.

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key to get buyers to agree to an exclusionary contract, whether partial or full, a seller will typically have to offer some inducements chicago-school critique: it is not possible for the seller to compensate for the buyer s loss and at the same time make itself better off. an incumbent competes against a potential entrant. The incumbent s marginal cost is c, the entrant s marginal cost is c. Suppose c > c. Suppose also that if the entrant comes into the market, competition between the two sellers will result in a per-unit price of c to the buyer. can the incumbent profitably exclude the entrant by inducing the buyer to sign an exclusive dealing contract C = (100%, x, p)?

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key to get buyers to agree to an exclusionary contract, whether partial or full, a seller will typically have to offer some inducements chicago-school critique: it is not possible for the seller to compensate for the buyer s loss and at the same time make itself better off. an incumbent competes against a potential entrant. The incumbent s marginal cost is c, the entrant s marginal cost is c. Suppose c > c. Suppose also that if the entrant comes into the market, competition between the two sellers will result in a per-unit price of c to the buyer. can the incumbent profitably exclude the entrant by inducing the buyer to sign an exclusive dealing contract C = (100%, x, p)?

Some background Rasmusen, Ramseyer, and Wiley (1991), Naked Exclusion suppose the entrant s technology is characterized by economies of scale. Given the right set of beliefs, the incumbent seller may be able to induce buyers to accept its contract with a trivial inducement Segal and Whinston (2000), Naked Exclusion: Comment if the buyers could coordinate their decisions, exclusion would not arise (as they would all want to reject the seller s ED contract).

Some background Rasmusen, Ramseyer, and Wiley (1991), Naked Exclusion suppose the entrant s technology is characterized by economies of scale. Given the right set of beliefs, the incumbent seller may be able to induce buyers to accept its contract with a trivial inducement Segal and Whinston (2000), Naked Exclusion: Comment if the buyers could coordinate their decisions, exclusion would not arise (as they would all want to reject the seller s ED contract).

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key an incumbent competes against a potential entrant. The incumbent s marginal cost is c, the entrant s marginal cost is c. Suppose c > c. Suppose also that if the entrant comes into the market, competition between the two sellers will result in a per-unit price of c to the buyer. can the incumbent profitably exclude the entrant by inducing the buyer to sign a partial exclusionary contract C = {s, x, p} s is the minimum share the buyer must purchase from the seller x is the inducement needed to get the buyer to accept p is the per-unit price at which the seller commits to sell the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (assuming the entrant is not foreclosed)

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key an incumbent competes against a potential entrant. The incumbent s marginal cost is c, the entrant s marginal cost is c. Suppose c > c. Suppose also that if the entrant comes into the market, competition between the two sellers will result in a per-unit price of c to the buyer. can the incumbent profitably exclude the entrant by inducing the buyer to sign a partial exclusionary contract C = {s, x, p} s is the minimum share the buyer must purchase from the seller x is the inducement needed to get the buyer to accept p is the per-unit price at which the seller commits to sell the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (assuming the entrant is not foreclosed)

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (if the entrant is not foreclosed) p (if the entrant is foreclosed) α 1 : the probability that entry occurs if only one buyer signs contract (assume entrant must incur fixed costs, which are stochastic) S( ): the buyer s surplus as function of the per unit price she pays. then the expected surplus of the buyer if she agrees to the contract is α 1 S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )S(p) + x whereas her surplus if she does not agree to the contract is S(c) so, the necessary inducement to get the buyer to accept is x S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p))

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (if the entrant is not foreclosed) p (if the entrant is foreclosed) α 1 : the probability that entry occurs if only one buyer signs contract (assume entrant must incur fixed costs, which are stochastic) S( ): the buyer s surplus as function of the per unit price she pays. then the expected surplus of the buyer if she agrees to the contract is α 1 S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )S(p) + x whereas her surplus if she does not agree to the contract is S(c) so, the necessary inducement to get the buyer to accept is x S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p))

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (if the entrant is not foreclosed) p (if the entrant is foreclosed) α 1 : the probability that entry occurs if only one buyer signs contract (assume entrant must incur fixed costs, which are stochastic) S( ): the buyer s surplus as function of the per unit price she pays. then the expected surplus of the buyer if she agrees to the contract is α 1 S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )S(p) + x whereas her surplus if she does not agree to the contract is S(c) so, the necessary inducement to get the buyer to accept is x S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p))

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the average price paid by the buyer under this contract is p a = sp + (1 s)c (if the entrant is not foreclosed) p (if the entrant is foreclosed) α 1 : the probability that entry occurs if only one buyer signs contract (assume entrant must incur fixed costs, which are stochastic) S( ): the buyer s surplus as function of the per unit price she pays. then the expected surplus of the buyer if she agrees to the contract is α 1 S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )S(p) + x whereas her surplus if she does not agree to the contract is S(c) so, the necessary inducement to get the buyer to accept is x S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p))

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the incumbent will offer the minimum inducement necessary x = S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p)) but if all buyers sign the contract, then expected surplus is α n S(p a ) + (1 α n )S(p) + x = S(c) (α 1 α n )(S(p a ) S(p)) Each buyer receives less than S(c) - something that can be exploited.

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the incumbent will offer the minimum inducement necessary x = S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p)) but if all buyers sign the contract, then expected surplus is α n S(p a ) + (1 α n )S(p) + x = S(c) (α 1 α n )(S(p a ) S(p)) Each buyer receives less than S(c) - something that can be exploited.

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key the incumbent will offer the minimum inducement necessary x = S(c) S(p a ) + (1 α 1 )(S(p a ) S(p)) but if all buyers sign the contract, then expected surplus is α n S(p a ) + (1 α n )S(p) + x = S(c) (α 1 α n )(S(p a ) S(p)) Each buyer receives less than S(c) - something that can be exploited.

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key our idea: although partial exclusionary contracts may be less effective in driving a rival seller from the market other things equal, the cost of getting buyers to agree to the contract will be substantially less under exclusive dealing, the seller has to compensate each buyer for the full loss in surplus due to the rival s exclusion with partial exclusionary contracts, the seller can exploit externalities across buyers exclusion can be purchased relatively cheaply each buyer only has to be compensated for its marginal contribution to the exclusion of the rival seller the negative externalities imposed on it by other buyers accepting the seller s contract are not compensated turns exclusion story from a coordination game to a prisoner s dilemma

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key our idea: although partial exclusionary contracts may be less effective in driving a rival seller from the market other things equal, the cost of getting buyers to agree to the contract will be substantially less under exclusive dealing, the seller has to compensate each buyer for the full loss in surplus due to the rival s exclusion with partial exclusionary contracts, the seller can exploit externalities across buyers exclusion can be purchased relatively cheaply each buyer only has to be compensated for its marginal contribution to the exclusion of the rival seller the negative externalities imposed on it by other buyers accepting the seller s contract are not compensated turns exclusion story from a coordination game to a prisoner s dilemma

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key our idea: although partial exclusionary contracts may be less effective in driving a rival seller from the market other things equal, the cost of getting buyers to agree to the contract will be substantially less under exclusive dealing, the seller has to compensate each buyer for the full loss in surplus due to the rival s exclusion with partial exclusionary contracts, the seller can exploit externalities across buyers exclusion can be purchased relatively cheaply each buyer only has to be compensated for its marginal contribution to the exclusion of the rival seller the negative externalities imposed on it by other buyers accepting the seller s contract are not compensated turns exclusion story from a coordination game to a prisoner s dilemma

Understanding the buyer s incentive is key our idea: although partial exclusionary contracts may be less effective in driving a rival seller from the market other things equal, the cost of getting buyers to agree to the contract will be substantially less under exclusive dealing, the seller has to compensate each buyer for the full loss in surplus due to the rival s exclusion with partial exclusionary contracts, the seller can exploit externalities across buyers exclusion can be purchased relatively cheaply each buyer only has to be compensated for its marginal contribution to the exclusion of the rival seller the negative externalities imposed on it by other buyers accepting the seller s contract are not compensated turns exclusion story from a coordination game to a prisoner s dilemma

The Model three kinds of players: an incumbent firm (I ), a potential entrant (E), and N 2 homogenous and independent buyers each buyer has a downward-sloping demand q( ) I has marginal cost c, E has marginal cost c < c; the entrant therefore has cost advantage δ c c E must incur fixed cost for entry f (0, Nδq(c)), where f has distribution G ( ) and density function g( )

Timing of the game period 1: I offers each buyer exclusionary contract C = {s, x, p}, where s the minimum share, p per-unit price, x lump-sum payment period 2: Buyers decide whether to accept or reject the offer period 3: E learns the value of f and decides whether or not to enter period 4: I and E (if active) compete a la Bertrand by setting prices. If a buyer has agreed to I s exclusionary contract, then it must buy at least s share from the incumbent at the price p when entry occurs, but can buy the remaining 1 s share from the entrant at a price c.

Miscellaneous π(p) = (p c)q(p) denotes incumbent s profit S(p) denotes buyer s surplus D(p) S(c) S(p) π(p) denotes deadweight loss free buyer if buyer has not signed the incumbent s contract captive buyer if buyer has signed the incumbent s contract

Pricing game no entry: free buyers pay p m and obtain S(p m ) in surplus captive buyers pay p and obtain S(p) + x in surplus. with entry: free buyers pay c and obtain S(c) in surplus captive buyers pay p a = sp + (1 s)c and obtain S(p a ) + x in surplus

Entrant s entry decision if E does not enter, then E earns zero. if E enters, then E incurs cost f and earns n (1 s) δq(p a ) from captive buyers and (N n)δq(c) from free buyers therefore, it is profitable for E to enter if and only if f Π E (n, s) n (1 s) δq(p a ) + (N n) δq(c). the probability of entry is thus α n = G (Π E (n, s))

Buyers accept or reject if all buyers reject contract offer, then entry occurs with probability one and each buyer earns S(c) but notice that I can choose x such that each buyer prefers to accept its contract even if all other buyers reject it (1 α 1 )S(p) + α 1 S(p a ) + x > S(c), or in other words, I can always choose x > x (s, p), where x (s, p) S(c) ((1 α 1 )S(p) + α 1 S(p a ))

Characterization of Equilibria with some weak assumptions on the distribution of f, one can show if x > x (s, p) then the unique coalition-proof equilibrium is for all buyers to accept the contract if x < x (s, p) then the unique coalition-proof equilibrium is for all buyers to reject the contract

Contractual Externalities when the incumbent pays x (s, p), each captive buyer obtains a surplus strictly lower than S(c): U A (N) = (1 α N )S(p) + α N S(p a ) + x (s, p) = S(c) (α 1 α N ) (S(p a ) S(p)) for each captive buyer, acceptance of contract contributes to partial exclusivity by reducing probability of entry from one to α 1 whereas acceptance by other N 1 buyers imposes negative externalities by reducing likelihood of entry from α 1 to α N, thereby bringing an expected welfare loss of (α 1 α N ) (S(p a ) S(p))

Contractual Externalities each captive buyer is compensated for its own contribution to exclusion, however negative externalities imposed by other buyers are not compensated the incumbent can potentially exploit this externality

Main Result Proposition There exists a contract offer C = {s, x, p} such that the incumbent earns positive expected payoff in the PCPNE of the continuation game, with s (0, 1), p > c, and x > x (s, p)

Entry, Prices, and Welfare a distinguishing feature of the model is that entry occurs with positive probability (but less than one) even though the seller engages in exclusionary conduct and would prefer that entry not occur the possibility thus arises that the seller and the entrant (or rival seller) may co-exist in the market with each having positive sales, despite the seller s exclusionary conduct nevertheless, the exclusionary contracts will still be anticompetitive

Conclusion recent years have seen the emergence of minimum-share requirements contracts; we show how they can be used by an incumbent seller to ineffi ciently deter entry in the presence of scale economies the paper builds on previous work on naked exclusion by RRW and SW, but differs in finding that minimum-share requirements can be profitable even when fully exclusionary contracts would not be a feature of the model is that welfare may be harmed even if exclusionary conduct does not deter entry or raise E s costs however interpretation of our results for policy should be tempered. We have only shown that minimum-share requirements can be anticompetitive, not that they actually are in any given setting

Conclusion recent years have seen the emergence of minimum-share requirements contracts; we show how they can be used by an incumbent seller to ineffi ciently deter entry in the presence of scale economies the paper builds on previous work on naked exclusion by RRW and SW, but differs in finding that minimum-share requirements can be profitable even when fully exclusionary contracts would not be a feature of the model is that welfare may be harmed even if exclusionary conduct does not deter entry or raise E s costs however interpretation of our results for policy should be tempered. We have only shown that minimum-share requirements can be anticompetitive, not that they actually are in any given setting

Conclusion recent years have seen the emergence of minimum-share requirements contracts; we show how they can be used by an incumbent seller to ineffi ciently deter entry in the presence of scale economies the paper builds on previous work on naked exclusion by RRW and SW, but differs in finding that minimum-share requirements can be profitable even when fully exclusionary contracts would not be a feature of the model is that welfare may be harmed even if exclusionary conduct does not deter entry or raise E s costs however interpretation of our results for policy should be tempered. We have only shown that minimum-share requirements can be anticompetitive, not that they actually are in any given setting

Conclusion recent years have seen the emergence of minimum-share requirements contracts; we show how they can be used by an incumbent seller to ineffi ciently deter entry in the presence of scale economies the paper builds on previous work on naked exclusion by RRW and SW, but differs in finding that minimum-share requirements can be profitable even when fully exclusionary contracts would not be a feature of the model is that welfare may be harmed even if exclusionary conduct does not deter entry or raise E s costs however interpretation of our results for policy should be tempered. We have only shown that minimum-share requirements can be anticompetitive, not that they actually are in any given setting