The Economics of Grazing Livestock on Public Lands

Similar documents
PUBLIC GRAZING IN THE WEST: THE IMPACT OF RANGELAND REFORM 94

US Code (Unofficial compilation from the Legal Information Institute) TITLE 43 - PUBLIC LANDS CHAPTER 37 PUBLIC RANGELANDS IMPROVEMENT

ALBERTA GRAZING LEASE 2005 IN-KIND COST SURVEY RESULTS

Current Grazing Practices and the Relationship to Communities

OTHER FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Calculating Crop Share, Cash and Flexible Cash Lease Rates

MODERNIZING ALBERTA S PUBLIC LAND GRAZING FRAMEWORK

A Comparison of Economic Impact Estimates for Changes in the Federal Grazing Fee: Secondary vs. Primary Data I/O Models 1

SRD Grazing Lease Rental Rates

GENERAL ASSESSMENT DEFINITIONS

AN EVALUATION OF THE PRIA GRAZING FEE FORMULA

Grazing Disposition Royalty Proposal Alberta Environment and Parks

Montana Trust Land Grazing Lease Rate Valuation Analysis

Economics of Leasing. Introduction

Flexible Farm Lease Agreements

Stocker Lease Agreements

AGRICULTURAL LEASING STUDY

Agricultural Leasing Study

Comparables Sales Price (Old Version)

The Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008 modified many aspects of the previous payment limitations provisions enacted in past Farm Bills. Produc

December 21, The specific provisions of P.L that apply solely to the CDCA are:

April 26, 2013* Announcement: Student Housing conducts 37 th annual City of Davis Vacancy and Rental Rate Survey.

MODERNIZING ALBERTA S PUBLIC LAND GRAZING FRAMEWORK

The Impact of Market Rate Vacancy Increases Eleven-Year Report

Return to Iowa farmland versus S&P 500

The Financial Accounting Standards Board

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

Impact Of Financing Terms On Nominal Land Values: Implications For Land Value Surveys

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary

So You ve Inherited a Farm, Now What?

Financing a farm can be a challenge. It is one thing to dream of farming, quite another to make it a reality. It is important to be realistic in

A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF GRAZING FEES ON MONTANA PUBLIC SCHOOL LANDS AND OTHER GRAZING LANDS IN MONTANA KENNETH L. SIDERIUS

PREFACE This publication was developed by the Southern Farm Management Ex tension Committee in response to the many questions being raised by Southern

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

DRAFT REVISED NORTHERN CHEYENNE LAW & ORDER CODE TITLE 21 GRAZING ORDINANCE

Before the Minnesota Public Utilities Commission State of Minnesota. Docket No. E002/GR Exhibit (LMC-1) Property Taxes

Transferring Farm Machinery through a Lease Agreement Michael Langemeier, Associate Director, Center for Commercial Agriculture

Chapter 8. How much would you pay today for... The Income Approach to Appraisal

AGENDA ITEM 6. R Meeting No November 13, 2013 AGENDA ITEM. Grazing Tenant Selection for Driscoll and McDonald Ranches

Initial sales ratio to determine the current overall level of value. Number of sales vacant and improved, by neighborhood.

Agricultural Leasing in Maryland

Chapter 8. How much would you pay today for... The Income Approach to Appraisal

Pasture Leases. Overview. Overview. Finding and assessing land/tenants. What to include in the lease. Type of leases

STATE TAX COMMISSION QUALIFIED AGRICULTURAL PROPERTY EXEMPTION GUIDELINES

Q. How is Agricultural property valued? A. GENERAL INFORMATION Many states have laws regarding the preferential assessment of agricultural land.

CRS Report for Congress

Ron Shultz, Director of Policy Washington State Conservation Commission

Volume Title: Real Wages in Manufacturing, Volume Author/Editor: Albert Rees, Donald P. Jacobs

BUYER'S DISCLOSURE STATEMENT

CABARRUS COUNTY 2016 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Housing in ICP 2011: Outstanding Issues

ANSWERS TO COMMONLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT AGRICULTURAL LAND VALUE IN KANSAS

EXPLANATION OF MARKET MODELING IN THE CURRENT KANSAS CAMA SYSTEM

How to Determine the Value of a Storage Property from Financial Reports. Presented by: Joe Linsalata

AN ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS OF. Muzaf far Iqbal for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in. Agricultural and Resource Economics presented on September

Cornerstone 2 Basic Valuation of Machinery and Equipment

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Frequently Asked Questions on Sustainable & Long-Term Leases in Minnesota

Leasing Arrangements for Cattle

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

The Cost of Property, Plant, Equipment

Kent/MSU Extension Attn: Stacy Byers 775 Ball Ave NE Grand Rapids, MI Tel: (616)

Comparing the Stock Market and Iowa Land Values: A Question of Timing Michael Duffy ISU Department of Economics

NCGS , ,

procedures Basic Appraisal F i n a l Examination #2 2 nd edition

SLIDES: Livestock Grazing on the Public Lands

CITY COUNCIL JUNE 6, 2016 PUBLIC HEARING

2017 Reappraisal Preliminary Report. February 6, 2017

Contract-Related Intangible

Project Economics: The Value of Leasing. Russell Banham, Savills

Following is an example of an income and expense benchmark worksheet:

1. Introduction. 1. Formal Disposition 2. Authorization 3. Approval. ESRD, Public Land Management, 2014, No.2. Effective Date: January 30, 2014

Business Valuation More Art Than Science

ON THE HAZARDS OF INFERRING HOUSING PRICE TRENDS USING MEAN/MEDIAN PRICES

FISCAL IMPACT ANALYSIS Proposed Abington Terrace Development Abington Township, Montgomery County

Guidelines for the Consideration of Applications for the Demolition or Moving of Structures Within the Northville Historic District

Trulia s Rent vs. Buy Report: Full Methodology

State of Alaska Department of Natural Resources Division of Agriculture

Best Practices for Lease Negotiations -/) -

TECHNICAL INFORMATION PAPER VALUATION OF SELF STORAGE FACILITIES

FOR LEASE STATE TRUST LAND

THE TREND OF REAL ESTATE TAXATION IN KANSAS, 1910 TO 1942¹

The Local Impact of Home Building in Douglas County, Nevada. Income, Jobs, and Taxes generated. Prepared by the Housing Policy Department

STATE OF NEW MEXICO COUNTY OF EDDY ORDINANCE NO: 41 LAND USE POLICIES AND PROCEDURES FOR FEDERAL, STATE AND COUNTY

Identifying Troubled NYCHA Developments in Brooklyn. Cost Considerations for Rehabilitating Troubled NYCHA Brooklyn Developments.

Rent Policy. Approved on: 9 December 2010 Board of Management Consolidated November 2015

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers?

Chapter 13. The Market Approach to Value

So You ve Inherited a Farm, Now What?

Landlord s Checklist Of Silent Lease Issues (Second Edition)

IN THE OREGON TAX COURT MAGISTRATE DIVISION Property Tax ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

Six Steps to a Completed Appraisal Report

Economic Impacts of MLS Home Sales and Purchases In The province of Québec and The Greater Montréal Area

December 16, Announcement: Student Housing conducts 36 th annual City of Davis Vacancy and Rental Rate Survey.

HOMEBUYER DISCLOSURE STATEMENT (MAMMOTH LAKES HOUSING, INC.)

Mammoth Lakes Housing, Inc. Purchasable Workforce Housing Policies and Guidelines Summary

Briefing: Rent reductions

2013 Update: The Spillover Effects of Foreclosures

820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

Transcription:

Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Economic Research Institute Study Papers Economics and Finance 1991 The Economics of Grazing Livestock on Public Lands Darwin Nielsen Utah State University Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri Recommended Citation Nielsen, Darwin, "The Economics of Grazing Livestock on Public Lands" (1991). Economic Research Institute Study Papers. Paper 9. https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri/9 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics and Finance at DigitalCommons@USU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic Research Institute Study Papers by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@USU. For more information, please contact dylan.burns@usu.edu.

December 1991 Study Paper No. ERI 91-07 THE ECONOMICS OF GRAZING LIVESTOCK ON PUBLIC LANDS By Darwin Nielsen

1 THE ECONOMICS OF GRAZING LIVESTOCK ON PUBLIC LANDS by Darwin B. Nielsen There is a wide spectrum of beliefs as to how good a deal it is to graze livestock on public lands. If you are a livestockman from a nonpublic land state, you probably would like to get some grazing where the fee is about one-tenth of,what you have to pay. This would be the situation where private leases sell for $12 to $15 per AUM and public fees are $1. 35/AUM. If you are a critic of government programs, you cannot under~ stand why the fees do not cover the cost of the grazing program. If you are a public land rancher and you keep account of what it costs you to graze public lands, you contend that you are paying all it is worth. Each one of the perceptions of publi~ land grazi~g have some validity depending on the perspective of the viewer. Let me give you a perspective on grazing fees, both public and private, based on over 20 years experience and research that might shed some light on why there is so much diversity of opinion on the subject. The term' "grazing fee" encompasses too many different lease arrangements to be meaningful in and of itself. Therefore, comparisons of grazing fees without defining what is included is misleading. To illustrate this point, let us take an example from another segment of the economy, house rent. Assume two homes are the same size, the same age, and in about the same condition. Would one expect the rent to be the same on the two homes?, Suppose one prospective renter works within a mile of one of the homes while the other is 15 miles away. One home is completely furnished and the landlord pays all of the utilities; the other is rented unfurnished and the tenant pays all utilities. It is possible

2 that one home could be located in a neighborhood where the crime rate is high and everything not nailed down is stolen. Obviously, one -would have to know everything about the lease arrangements before direct comparisons of rent could be made, even though the products (the houses) are the same. There is equally as much diversity in grazing leases. For example, Case I--the landlord performs all of the management of the rangeland and the livestock, including paying death loss above an agreed upon percentage. Case II--raw land is leased and the landlord does little more than collect the fees and pay the taxes. These cases represent the extremes while other leases cover the spectrum between these end points. As might be expected, grazing fees vary a great deal within this market, even though the product, an AUM, is fairly homogeneous. At the present time, the money collected by the government in grazing fees is a relatively insignificant part of the total cost of grazing. In order~o make legitimate comparisons of public and private grazing fees, one should look at the total cost to the user. Data were collected from ranchers in all of the western public land states to estimate the total cost of leasing public lands and the total cost of leasing comparable private grazing lands. These cost items are averaged and summarized in Table 1. Based on these data, the 1966 public grazing fee would be $1.23 per AUM if the goal was to collect full market value. In addition to the base fee, the fees would be kept current with private lease rates by an annual adjustment in fees based on an index of private lease rates in the west. If one accepts the new philosophy of collecting full market value for all goods and services provided by the government, the above position

3 TABLE 1. Summary of Combined Average Public Costs and Private Costs per Animal Unit Month--1966 a Combined Combined Public Private Public Private Itemized Costs Costs Costs Costs Costs $ $ $ $ 1. Lost animals 0.60 0.37 0.70 0.65 2. Association fee 0.08 0.04 3. Veterinary 0.11 0.13 o. 11 0.11 4. Moving livestock to and from allotments 0.24 0.25 0.42 0.38 5. Herding 0.46 0.19 1.33 1.16 6. Salting and feeding 0.56 0.83 0.55 0.45 7. Travel to and from allotments 0.32 0.25 0.49 0.43 8. Water 0.08 0.06 0.15 o. 16 9. Fence maintenance 0.24 0.25 0.09 o. 15 10. Horse O. 16 0.10 0.16 0.07 11. Water maintenance o. 19 0.15 0.11 0.09 12. Development depreciation O. 11 0.03 0.09 0.02 13. Other costs o. 13 0.14 0.29 0.2-2 14. Private lease rate 1.79 1.77 Total Costs 3.28 4.54 4.53 5.66 Difference 1.26 b 1.13 b Weighted Average 1.23 adeveloped from data analysis of the grazing fees technical committee --November 29, 1968. b The difference weighted by corresponding AUMs results in weighted average of $1.23. on grazing fees appears fair and reasonable. Thus, one might ask why has the livestock industry put up such a determined fight against the new policy. fee The livestock industry's main thrust in the grazing fee controversy has not been against the concept of the government charging full market value for the use of its grazing lands. The controversy has centered on the cost items used to arrive at the new base fee of $1.23 per AUM. They agree with the items listed in Table 1 but believe very strongly that one

major cost of grazing on public lands has been omitted. to graze public lands has taken on a value. 4 The authorization This value shows up either as a permit value directly or as an increase in the value of the commensurate property of the rancher. Most of the current public land grazing permittees have purchased their permits from other ranchers. Thus, the permit represents a capital asset, just like their other real property. It is the livestock industry's position that a "fair" grazing fee must take into account a return on capital invested in the permit, which is a cost just as real as the other items listed in Table 1. on their investment in the grazing permit, the If ranchers were allowed a 3 to 6 percent return there would have been no justification for an increase in the grazing fee base in 1966. We have a case where both sides of an tssue claim, with justification, that,their position is fair and reasonable. This might help explain why there has been such a long hard battle between the agencies and the livestockmen over an issu~ -that both- stdesadmit -has taken more time and energy than the dollars involved would justify. The livestock industry was able to get a bill into the Congress on,.. public lands. In this bill there was a section on grazing fees. The bill, now known as the "Public Rangelands Improvement Act of 1978,n passed Congress and was signed by the President. fees is as follows: The section pertaining to grazing Sec. 6. (a) For the grazing years 1979 through 1985, the Secretaries of Agric~lture and Interior shali charge the fee for domestic livestock grazing on the public rangelands which Congress finds represents the economic value of the use of the land to the user, and under which Congress finds fair market value for public grazing equals the $1.23 base established by the 1966 Western Livestock Grazing Survey multiplied by the result of the Forage Value Index (computed annually from data supplied by the Economic Research Service) added to the Combined Index (Beef Cattle Price Index minus the Price Paid Index) and divided by 100: Provided, That the annual increase or decrease in such fee for any given year

5 shall be limited to not more than plus or minus 25 per centum of the previous year's fee (Public Rangelands Improvement Act of 1978). The two new indices added to the fee formula by the "Public Rangeland Improvement Act of 1978" are based on ranchers' ability to pay. A difference of opinion about the long-term implications of adding indices to the fee formula caused the 1985 review clause to be into the Act. A summary of their reasons follows: The formula was established on a 7-year trial basis because "many groups and individuals concerned with the improvement of the range disagree with the concept of grazing fees dependent on beef cattle prices and the ranchers' ability to pay, and do not believe lower fees will eliminate overgrazing. This trial period will give all sides an opportunity to study the effects of tying the fee to beef prices, and also allow the Secretaries to refine their data on the value of Federal grazing lands as compared to privately-owned lands." (House Report No. 95-1122). At the end of the trial period, no later than December 31, 1985, the Secretaries are to repor~ to Congress on the results of their grazing fee study. these inserted It is not clear where the argument about the connection between grazing fees and overgrazing comes from. Given the usual amount of rancher discretion allowed in setting stocking rates on public lands (none), appears there;s no empirical evidence that fee levels and overgrazing are related. A Presidential Order in 1986 set the minimum fee at $1.35/AUM retained the grazing fee formula with the three indices. formula is as follows: fair market value = $1.23 (FVI) + (BPI - PPI) loa it and The current fee where $1.23 = 1966 base fee, FVI = forage value index, BPI = beef price index, and PPI = prices paid index. The indices used to get the $1.35/AUM fee were based on the fee set for 1985 as follows: $ 1.23 (242) + (262-395) loa = $1.35

6 The nonfee costs of using public lands have increased substantially since the 1966 study. Costs of repeating the 1966 grazing fee study prohibit collecting new data to update these costs. It has been estimated that it would cost 3 to 4 million dollars to get this new information. An approximation of what these nonfee costs would be can be made by indexing the 1966 cost items up to the present time. An example of what these costs would have been in January 1987 is given in Table 2. A mistake that many critics of public land grazing fee policies make is that they do not make their comparisons of public and private fees on the same basis. The total cost of using these lands should be used when comparisons are made. For example, the total cost of using public lands $12.04/AUM should be compared to private lease rates where the landlord provides all services. Instead, one usually sees $1.35 per AUM for public compared to $10 to $12 for private rangelands. A continued controversy over public land grazing fees appears to be as inevitable as death and taxes. All of the information presented on the cost of public land grazing is based on an average for all permittees. Thus, the data represents few ranchers exactly. There is a considerable amount of variation in any of I the variables considered in valuing grazing. With this variable information available within this broad market area, one can find data to substantiate almost any position one wants to take. High nonfee cost ranches could be used to "prove" that public lands are hardly worth using. On the other hand, low nonfee cost ranches could be used to "prove" that ranchers are being subsidized by the government and creating unfair competition for nonpublic land ranchers.

. 7 TABLE 2. Fee and Nalfee Costs of Grazing Federal Lands (updated with January 1987 Index NlJ1bers) Item Lost animals Association fees Veterinarian ~ving livestock Herding Salting & feeding Travel Water Fence maintenance Horse cost Water maintenance Dev. depreciation Other cost IndEf«Index 1966 No. 1977 No. 1987 $0.60 x 1.68 (meat animals/prices received) = $1.008 x 1.46 = $ 1.47 0.08 x 2.01 0.11 x 2.26 0.24 x 2.30 0.46 x 2.26 0.56 x 2.10 0.32 x 2.18 0.08 x 2.01 0.24 x 2.28 0.16 x 1.86 0.19 x 2.28 0.11 x 2.01 0.13 x 2.01 (production items) (\II8ge rates) (autos, trucks, & \ll8ge rates) = (wage rates) = ( autos, trucks, & feed) = (autos, trucks, fuel, & energy) = (production i terns) = (wages, building, & f arcing) = (feed) = (wages, building, & fercing) = (production items) = (production items) = 1987 FEE COSTS BLI'I & FS = $1.35/AlJYI TOTAL DlST 1987 TOTAL NONFEE OOSTS BL~ & FS = $1.35 + $10.69 = $12.04/AlJYI 0.1608 x 1.43 = 0.23 0.2486 x 1.59 = 0.40 0.5520 x 1.78 = 0.98 1.0396 x 1.59 = 1.64 1 1760 x 1.70 = 1.99 0.6976 x 1.77 = 1.23 0.1608 x 1.43 = 0.23 0.5448 x 1.47 = 0.80 0.2976 x 1.43 = 0.41 o.4313 x 1.47 = 0.63 0.2211 x 1.43 = 0.31 0.2613 x 1.43 = 0.37 = $10.69 * Indices taken fran USDA, 1978, Agricultural Prices. Arn.Jal. SuInary 1 m, Washington, D.C. s Econanics, Statistics, & Cooperatives Service, Jl.Ile; and USDA, 1987, Agricultural Prices, Washington, D.C.s National Agricultural Statistics Service, Jaruary..'"

8 It appears that government budgets for grazing programs are not going to provide funds for maintenance (replacement) or new construction of range improvements on public lands. asked Permittees are being asked or will be (maybe required) to pay these costs as part of their grazing permit. If this is the case, the nonfee costs will increase because of new investments in public lands not just because the general price level of inputs has increased. Because of the "nature of the beast," public lands have level management system. a double The agencies are required to manage the resources which include the allotments where livestock graze. In addition, the permittee is required to perform many land management functions. The agencies are paid for their management out of their grazing budgets. permittees are paid through credit given in the nonfee costs. The rt is not surprising that grazing programs do not pay the cost to the government of maintaining them. Before the conclusion is reached that grazing should be terminated, one should consider the benefits. Rangeland, a -renewable resource, has produced range forage which has been converted into useful products to. support local, state, and national economies. REFERENCES Nielsen, Darwin B., and E. Boyd Wennergren, Public Policy and Graz1ng Fees on Federal lands: Some Unresolved Issues. Land and Water Law Review 5(2, 1970). Public Rangelands Improvement Act of 1918. Public Law 95-514. U.S. Department of Agriculture. 1978. Agricultural Pricesz _ Annual -Summary 1977. Washington, D.C.: Economics, Statistics, & Cooperatives Service. June. a 1987. Agricultural Prices. Washington, D.C.: Nati-onal Agricultural Statistics Service. January.