A Transaction-cost Analysis of the Land Development Process

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Transaction-cost Analysis of the Land Development Process"

Transcription

1 Urban Studies, Vol. 41, No. 13, , December 2004 A Transaction-cost Analysis of the Land Development Process Edwin Buitelaar [Paper first received, November 2003; in final form, June 2004] Summary. The production of our built environment involves many transaction costs. We want to avoid unnecessary transaction costs. Nevertheless, we hardly take account of transaction costs when considering different ways of organising the development process. The most important reason is probably the difficulty in identifying them. This paper shows why transaction costs are important and offers a method for identifying them. With this method, it is possible to compare the efficiency of different institutional arrangements. Introduction Transaction cost economics is not new. The nature of the firm, which was written by the founding father of new institutional or transaction-cost economics Ronald Coase, appeared in The entrance of this branch of economics into planning theory, however, is of a much more recent date. 1 Many economic analyses of planning were (and still are) based on traditional welfare economics (see, for example, Harrison, 1977; Heikkila, 2000). Webster and Lai (2003, p. 219) give two reasons for the growing attention given to Coasian economics in the past decade. The first is the Nobel Prize Coase received in the early 1990s. The second is that the old paradigms have lost their power in a period when the role of public land-use planning is under pressure. Alexander introduced the consideration of transaction costs into planning theory with his article A transaction-cost theory of planning in There, planning is treated from a transaction-cost perspective as being a process of co-ordination such as is analysed in general terms in institutional economics. This line of thought can be extended to the development process. 2 The development process can be regarded as a sort of production process: at a particular location, the built environment is changed i.e. produced (see Figure 1). 3 The production process has often been approached from a neo-institutional economic perspective (see, for example, Williamson, 1975, 1985). Since Alexander s article, transaction cost economics has been applied several times to market versus government issues in planning theory (Lai, 1994, 1997; Alexander, 2001a, 2001b; Buitelaar, 2003; Webster and Lai, 2003). Although these contributions provide Edwin Buitelaar is in the Nijmegen School of Management, University of Nijmegen, Thomas van Aquinostraat 3, PO Box 9108, 6500 HK Nijmegen, The Netherlands. Fax: e.buitelaar@fw.ru. The author gratefully acknowledges helpful suggestions on drafts of this paper, especially from Barrie Needham (University of Nijmegen), but also from Ernest Alexander (APD Alexander Planning and Design), Daniel Bromley (University of Wisconsin Madison), Roelof Verhage (Institut d Urbanisme de Lyon), Margo van den Brink, George de Kam and Arnoud Lagendijk (all of the University of Nijmegen) Print/ X On-line/04/ The Editors of Urban Studies DOI: /

2 2540 EDWIN BUITELAAR Figure 1. A simple model of the production process. Source: Christopher (1998, p. 13). us with useful insights, they lack (sufficient) operationalisation for empirical application. In this paper, I provide a transaction costs framework for comparing institutional arrangements in Western capitalist countries. These institutional arrangements can be regarded as devices for co-ordinating the development process, ranging from market to network to hierarchical forms. I operationalise the framework by focusing on user rights regimes, a type of institutional arrangement that is particularly important for land use planning. In addition, I provide a method for identifying transaction costs, which can be applied empirically. Before the operationalisation, I show which theoretical purposes a transaction-cost analysis might serve. In order to do that, it will be made clear what transaction costs are and why they are important. After that, I show that transaction costs can shed a different light on the discussion about efficiency by introducing the concept of process efficiency, which differs from the often used allocative or output efficiency. This is followed by the operationalisation of the framework, an empirical application to the development process of a housing site in the Netherlands which is used as a starting-point, after which reference is made to transaction costs in other institutional frameworks of planning in other countries. The paper ends with some concluding remarks. Transaction Costs Conceptually Transaction costs refer to all costs other than the costs of physical production (Lai, 1994, p. 84). Transaction costs emerge because we do not have perfect rationality and complete information as is assumed in many neo-classical models. Instead of that, there is bounded rationality, incomplete information and opportunism. Transaction costs are the costs that are incurred to increase the information available to us and to reduce uncertainty. For instance, before we buy a car we try to get information about prices, quality and service. Therefore, we compare different brands and different dealers. Those activities cost time, money and effort, in other words: transaction costs. Although the concept transaction costs suggests that only the costs around a transaction are involved, it is often used more broadly. If the costs of transacting between supplier and demander are too high, one of those two might decide to incorporate the activity of the other by acquiring it from the other. For example, a car factory might decide to incorporate the activity of distributing cars, because the transaction costs of outsourcing are too high. This shift towards a hierarchical form of organisation is called vertical integration. The transaction costs might now be lower because there is no transaction. But instead of that, the organisation has the internal costs of co-ordinating the activity that has been incorporated. These costs are agency costs, but are often also called transaction costs. 4 Some (for example, Hazeu, 2000, p. 74) argue that, because of the confusing nature of the term transaction costs, co-ordination costs is a better term. Nevertheless, because everyone is familiar with

3 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT 2541 Figure 2. Specifying the costs of the production process. transaction costs, and to prevent confusion, I continue using this term. Transaction costs can be further specified. First of all, there are (as already said) the costs of acquiring information, like a comparison of brands. In the case of land use planning, it can be, for example, research into residential preferences. These transaction costs are called information costs. Uncertainty can also be (and often is) reduced by using institutions. Landed property, for instance, means that there are rights and consequently (see Bromley, 1991) duties with respect to a particular piece of land. These reduce uncertainty about what can and cannot be done with that land, and by whom. North (1990a, p. 3) defines institutions as: the rules of the game in a society or, more formally, the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction. Institutions are created or changed, after which they are used. 5 The creation and use (see, for this distinction, Furubotn and Richter, 1991, p. 8) of institutions involves costs: transaction costs or, more specifically, institutional costs. In Figure 2, I have summarised the different costs of the production process in order to specify the concept of transaction costs. As will become clear, this paper focuses on the costs of creating and using institutions. It should be noted that costs are incurred to get more information about the institutions. Then, they are regarded as institutional costs, because they can be seen as part of the costs of using the institution. The costs of acquiring information independent of the institutional arrangements are what I call the information costs. The identification and measurement of transaction costs are not routine tasks. Hardly anyone who has tried this, has achieved completely satisfying results (Furubotn and Richter, 1991). Ball (1998, p. 1503) even argues that it is impossible to measure transaction costs. He concludes that, because of this, the empirical validity of transaction-cost minimising theory remains unclear. Transaction-cost theory as a positive theory is indeed questionable (see also Poulton, 1997). The doubts relate not only to the measurability of transaction costs, but also to the assumption that institutions move towards the lowest transaction costs i.e. efficiency. But many institutions persist while they are sometimes highly inefficient (Buitelaar et al., 2004). Whether measured or not, according to Furubotn and Richter (1991) transaction costs have a significant heuristic value. Heuristic in this sense means that identifying transaction costs is useful. But, why is it useful and we should we take (more) account of transaction costs? Transaction costs do not contribute directly to the output of a development process, like land, bricks, concrete and trees, in other words the production costs. From a perspective of cost efficiency, transaction costs can be seen as dead weight losses that have to be minimised. It is assumed (see also Webster, 1998) that the fewer the transaction

4 2542 EDWIN BUITELAAR costs, the more smooth and efficient the development process. Nevertheless, transaction costs are hardly incorporated in economic analyses. An example of this, given by van Keulen and Hoek (2003), is the public private partnership (PPP). People that favour PPPs claim that these partnerships add value to the project. But they often forget to mention the transaction costs. In the HSL Zuid (the Dutch part of the high-speed train connection between Amsterdam and Paris), for instance, high costs had to be incurred for consultancy, before the government chose a PPP. This paper focuses on the institutional costs, which are the costs of creating and using institutions in a development process. Reducing these costs increases the (process) efficiency of the development process in which they function. Consequently, comparing the costs of different institutional arrangements can be seen as comparing the efficiency of the development process. The general assumption behind this is that different institutional arrangements have different transaction costs (more precisely: institutional costs) borne by different people. Ideal types of institutional arrangements that I distinguish are: the market, the hierarchical and the network type. 6 Comparing the efficiency of different arrangements might contribute to a better design and use of institutional arrangements bearing in mind, hwever, that other criteria (for instance, effectiveness and legitimacy) are at least equally important. Process Efficiency Efficiency is a central concept in many economic analyses. Minimal transaction costs can be seen as maximum process efficiency (see also Webster, 1998). This efficiency concept is different from the traditional allocative efficiency. Allocative efficiency is an efficiency criterion, used in welfare economics, which indicates whether resources are allocated optimally. The optimum that is often used to refer to an efficient allocation of resources is the Pareto optimum. If an allocation is not optimal in the Pareto sense, it means that there is some reallocation of resources that would improve the welfare of at least one person without reducing anyone else s (Heikkila, 2000). Or in other words: there would be a possibility of increasing the valued output with the same (or even less) valued input. Therefore, allocative efficiency is also called output efficiency (Webster, 1998). Process efficiency does not emphasise the output. It differs from allocative efficiency in the sense that the output and the input of production costs are taken as given. Then, different ways of co-ordinating the given inputs to create the given outputs might be compared. One could see it is as a question like: how efficiently do we produce the built environment? The welfare economic question might be: how efficient is the use of the resources that produce the built environment? Allocative efficiency and process efficiency cannot be completely separated. More transaction costs lead to a greater input and hence a reduced allocative efficiency. In addition, when one wants to compare different development processes, the production costs and the output will never be completely the same. One must therefore be aware that differences in production costs i.e. input and output can have consequences for the transaction costs. Only the costs that are the result of the creation and use of institutions should be taken into account for determining the process efficiency and not the transaction costs that are caused by a difference in allocative efficiency. In my research, I focus on the concept of process efficiency, and not the welfare economic approach, for several reasons. The first reason is that I want to establish what the costs are of different institutional arrangements. Many economists use allocative efficiency to justify their statement that the market co-ordinates more efficiently than the government. The basis for this assertion goes back to Adam Smith s invisible hand. But what allocative efficiency measures is the allocation of resources. This is the result of various substantive choices of agents and agencies. Therefore we cannot, for instance, as is often done (see, for example, Ellickson,

5 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT ; Pennington, 2002), blame zoning (or other instruments of hierarchical co-ordination) for inefficient resource allocation. Zoning in itself is a neutral tool. It can, in principle, produce the same type of development with the same resources as the market would. The substantive choices made in a zoning plan can lead to the sub-optimal allocation of resources; the tool zoning cannot. The use of zoning (like any other form of co-ordination) involves transaction costs. These costs have to be regarded when we want to determine the process efficiency. So again, process efficiency judges ways of coordination, where allocative efficiency is more suitable for judging substantive choices. The second reason lies in the fact that welfare economics assumes that all collective objectives can be incorporated in the one criterion of allocative efficiency. I regard that as a simplification of the goals of collective action. Allocative efficiency is just one criterion (although an important one); another criterion could, for instance, be social stability. It should also be noted that many transaction-cost economists (for example, Williamson, 1995) see transaction costs as the overarching concept for judging different institutional arrangements. But, transaction costs are also just one criterion (besides, for instance, effectiveness, justice and legitimacy) for evaluating different forms of coordination. The third and last argument for using process efficiency is that the Pareto optimum, which is often referred to in order to operationalise allocative efficiency, is an unattainable situation. When there are still some gains from trade that have not been exhausted, the market is seen as inefficient. This means that there remain social costs (i.e. negative externalities). 7 In the welfare economic view, government intervention can in a situation of market inefficiency lead to a redistribution of resources, in order eventually to reach the Pareto optimum. 8 I suggest (see also Williamson, for example, 1995; Alexander, 2001a, 2001b) a comparison of different (existing) institutional arrangements on the basis of their transaction costs. Comparing the costs of different forms of co-ordination is a more realistic and practically manageable approach than comparing a practical to some ideal situation, like the Pareto optimum in welfare economics, or the zero transaction costs ideal in institutional economics (see North, 1990b). This is also referred to as remediability: it compares alternative feasible forms of governance, rather than referring to some hypothetical ideal (Alexander, 2001b; see also Williamson, 1995). It is important to note that we should not only take account of the total amount of transaction costs, but that we have to be aware of the distribution. Keogh and D Arcy argue that Instead of seeking a judgement on whether the property market as an entity is efficient, the institutional approach allows the possibility that the property market process may for example, be efficient for users but inefficient for developers (Keogh and D Arcy, 1999, p. 2412). Or, as Lindblom says what one person or group applauds as efficient another person or group may deplore as inefficient (Lindblom, 2001, p. 126). Operationalising the Framework Transaction costs are rarely measured in development processes. If transaction costs are at all quantified by the different parties involved, they are usually put as a nonspecified item on a balance sheet like, for example, administrative costs. Here, I put forward a method for identifying transaction costs. This is a necessary step before they can be measured. I do not provide a method for measuring transaction costs, but there is no theoretical difficulty in doing this, only the practical difficulty of the high (transaction) costs of doing it in terms of time, money and effort. To identify transaction costs, it is import-

6 2544 EDWIN BUITELAAR Figure 3. The user rights regime. ant to distinguish them from production costs. I use the model of the neo-classical market as point of reference to make the distinction. The difference, it is often argued, between neo-classical economics and new institutional economics is the lack of attention given to institutions and transaction costs in the former (see, for example, Eggertsson, 1990; North, 1990a). A neo-classical market is assumed to function frictionless and smoothly. Property rights are perfectly and costlessly specified and information is likewise costless to acquire (North, 1990a, p. 11). 9 This leads to a situation where there are only production costs (or transformation costs as North calls them) and no transaction costs. So, if we want to carry out a transaction-cost analysis of the development process, we must ask the question: would the costs that we find also be incurred in a neo-classical development process? If the answer is yes, those are production costs, if the answer is no they are transaction costs. This sounds too simple, but it will become clear that it is a very useful way to approach all the activities in the development process. I focus on the costs of creating and using an institutional arrangement, together the institutional costs. 10 The institutional arrangements that are particularly important for land use (and hence for land use planning) are what I call user rights regimes (see, for an extensive elaboration, Buitelaar, 2003). A user rights regime is a set of formal rules that defines and attenuates the right to use land and in that way co-ordinates changes in land use on a particular site. 11 This is done by means of rules from both the property rights regime and the spatial planning regime (see Figure 3). Institutions from the property rights regime are directed to facilitating exchange between the property owners, and between them and all others who do not have a right, but do have an interest, in that land. In most capitalist countries, we have the institution of private property with all its associated rights and duties (Bromley, 1991). The spatial planning regime provides tools to restrict the exercise of these private rights in the collective interest. It thereby regulates the market in land for example, by a zoning or land use plan. There are different types of user rights regimes, ranging from a market type, in which there are hardly any planning regulations, to a hierarchical, by which the market in user rights is strongly regulated. In addition, we have the network model of coordination, which is more directed to negotiation and collaboration. A user rights regime is used and (partly) created in a development process. Creating and using it involves costs. The property rights regime (the rules for the market in rights in land) is created at a national (or federal or state) level and used at a sitespecific level. The spatial planning regime is also created at a national level. The difference with the property rights regime is that the laws and rules are mainly procedural.

7 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT 2545 Table 1. User rights regimes and transaction costs Elements of the user rights regime in the development process Possible transaction-cost generating factors 1. Land exchange Yes or no Number of parties involved Conflict of interest Information about future possibilities Delineation (assignment) of rights Information re the delineation of rights: land registry or not Use of hierarchical means (such as compulsory purchase, pre-emption rights) 2. Making land use or zoning Yes or no plan/building ordinance, etc. (i.e. Stakeholder participation land use regulations) Appeal Number of parties involved Conflict of interest Structure of the plan: legally binding indicative Structure of the procedure: administrative political 3. Agreement (between, for Yes or no example, developer and Number of parties involved municipality) Conflict of interest Structure of agreement/contract: detailed flexible 4. Planning permission Yes, no or conditional Number of parties involved Conflict of interest Possibility of negotiation (planning gain) Possibility of appeal and the actual use of it Structure of the procedure: administrative political Structure of the permission: conditional unconditional The substantive filling-in occurs at a sitespecific level. The filling-in can on the one hand be seen as using the possibilities created by the spatial planning regime and on the other hand as creating the user rights regime. This creation can be in the form of a zoning or land use plan, after which the user rights regime is applied for instance, in the form of submitting and deciding upon planning permission or for a private property transaction. The level where property rights and spatial planning regimes are created, is not taken into account in the transaction-cost analysis of an individual development process, for the actors in that development process have no influence on this institutional environment (and the changes within it). It is therefore to the user rights regimes that I confine myself. What belongs in practice to these regimes and what does not, is shown in Table 1. In this table, we find four important points in the development process where the user rights regime is created (for example, land use plan) or used (for example, land exchange). To determine their affect on transaction costs there are several aspects that need to be taken into account and by which different regimes can be compared. In the second column of Table 1, some possible transaction-cost generating factors are enumerated.

8 2546 EDWIN BUITELAAR The first category in Table 1 deals with all the land transactions during the development process. These exchanges are facilitated by rules from the property rights regime. Using these institutions involves costs. The costs are further determined by how rights are delineated, the information about that, the information supply about future possibilities, the number of parties that want to acquire the land and whether or not hierarchical measures like compulsory purchase can be or are used. The second category that determines the height of the transaction costs is whether or not a land use/zoning plan is made. Related factors which might generate transaction costs are, for instance, the structure of the plan-making procedure and the plan, stakeholder participation, the number of stakeholders, conflict between them and appeal possibilities and use. The third category is agreement. In some development processes, agreements like restrictive covenants or (the British) planning agreements are signed among different parties to influence or determine the exercise of user rights. Again, the number of parties and their conflicts are important, as well as the structure of the agreement (detailed versus broad) for the size of the transaction costs. The last category is planning permission. Not every system (as we will see) has a land use plan and planning permission. If it does, it is important to see whether it is a political or administrative procedure, whether the permission is conditional or unconditional, if there is room for negotiation or appeal, how many parties are involved and whether their interests conflict. In the case study, all the (see also Table 1) categories will appear. The case study is used as a brief illustration of a transaction-cost analysis, in particular of the costs of and in a user rights regime. The case study serves as a startingpoint to discuss different designs of user rights regimes and the different costs of creating and using them. The approach is generally applicable to most Western countries. The countries must at least have the institution of private property, surrounded by rules from the property rights regime, possibly supplemented with rules that regulate land use from the spatial planning regime (see Figure 3). The Application to a Dutch Case To illustrate the user rights framework and the method for identifying transaction costs, it has been applied to a Dutch housing project. In this exploration, the sequence of activities will be briefly reconstructed, the transaction costs will be identified and the costs that can be attributed to the user rights regime will be dealt with. In addition, on several occasions reference is made to alternative regimes that have a different effect on transaction costs. The Dutch case is used as an illustration of the framework and as a starting-point for a discussion about different regimes and their transaction costs. Examples of alternative regimes are used to show that the framework does not only apply to the Dutch case, but can be used to analyse other Western capitalist regimes. The case that I have chosen is a housing project, called Lange-Veerstraat, of 71 dwellings in the municipality of Hilversum (between the cities of Amsterdam and Utrecht) in the Netherlands. Lange-Veerstraat is an urban regeneration project that (officially) started in 1994 and has not been finished yet. The motives for the municipality of Hilversum to start the project were the untidy appearance of the site, the high interest costs of the land the municipality acquired for a never-finished project in the early 1980s and the fact that a large part of the site was vacant after a school had been moved. The municipality pursued an active land policy, by acquiring most of the (remaining) land on the site. Most land was fairly easy to assemble, but one plot (of a printer) took a relatively long time to acquire. Finally, an agreement was reached in which both parties agreed upon the price and a new location. The municipality could not use compulsory purchase, because there was no legally binding land use plan (bestemmingsplan) at that time, which is a prerequisite for compulsory purchasing the land.

9 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT 2547 The project has been realised in close cooperation between the municipality and a developer. Although the municipality took the initiative and bought most of the land, the developer also acquired a plot and was involved from the start of the project. In March 2003 both parties signed an agreement in which the acquired land would be exchanged between the municipality and the developer. The municipality got all the land that is needed for public space and the developer got all the land necessary for its building plan. A clause was built into the contract that specified that the developer would not start the building process before 60 per cent of all the houses had been sold. Simultaneously with all the land development activities, a land use plan (bestemmingsplan) was established for the whole inner city of which the project is a part. Initially, the land use plan was not approved by the province on formal grounds. In 2002, it was finally approved by the province. The building plan that was made by the developer and approved by the municipality has been incorporated in the land use plan. Transaction and Production Costs The method described above for identifying transaction costs has been applied to the case study. In Table 2, a distinction has been made between production and transaction costs. For the sake of this paper, the following simplification has been made. It is impossible to reveal all the separate costs in a process. For instance, Lange-Veerstraat has already taken 10 years, in which many different costs have been incurred. Therefore, they have been identified on a more aggregated level by equating them with activities in the development process. The project start-up, for example, is an activity in the development process of Lange-Veerstraat in which many different costs can be found, like labour costs, print costs, deliberation between several departments within the municipality, deliberation between the municipality and the developer, etc. To reveal all these costs separately is practically impossible and theoretically unnecessary. The project start-up in itself is regarded as a transaction cost. The transaction costs are borne by various parties. Although there are many parties involved in a development process, the focus is on the developer and the municipality, because they are the most important parties that produce the built environment and therefore bear the majority of the transaction costs. To structure the development process, a division into three stages has been made the exploration, the plan-making and the execution stages (Koppenjan and van Ham, 2002). In the exploration stage, there is only one column, transaction costs, for there are no production costs. As said in the previous section, the neoclassical analysis of the development process forms a useful point of reference for distinguishing between production and transaction costs. The costs that contribute directly to building a house are the production costs; those costs would also have to be made in a frictionless neo-classical world. The other costs are the transaction costs, which have to be made because the acquisition of information, the creation and use of institutions are not without costs. To give an example, the acquisition of land would also be an activity that is needed in a neo-classical market : if you want to build a house you need land. 12 So, the price of land is a production cost. But negotiation and contract-making around the acquisition of land would not have existed in a frictionless market and are therefore transaction costs. Another example is the making of a building plan. A design is a necessary activity in the production process of a house or a housing block. The deliberation about the design between the municipality and the developer, in order for the developer to get planning permission, is part of the transaction costs, as are the costs of the negotiation between the developer and the architect.

10 2548 EDWIN BUITELAAR Table 2. Production and transaction costs in different stages of the development process of the Lange-Veerstraat in the municipality of Hilversum Exploration Plan making Execution Transaction costs Production costs Transaction costs Production costs Transaction costs Development plan inner Provisional Preparation for Demolition and Making city design of the land acquisition preparation of the specifications building plan from printer land Establishing and giving Definitive design Making more Tendering Application for project assignment to of the building detailed planning the project leader of the plan preconditions permission municipality Project start-up (Amicable) Administrative Preparation of the Treating acquisition of process of building site planning land approving the application provisional design (building plan and public space) Research project Move printer Deliberation with Building Putting out to boundaries architect about the tender provisional and definitive design Research design Provisional Deliberation with Maintenance after Delivery control possibilities design for public the architect of the project has space the municipality been finished about the public space Research residential Definitive design Preparation and Sale and letting Calculations of preferences and for public space starting the the land value possibilities bestemmingsplan procedure Assessment of Sales agreement Draw up sales Preparing sale ecological situation agreement and letting Historical research with More detailed soil regard to soil pollution research at the location of the printer Exploration of the Administrative buildings that had to process of move Research into commercial possibilities Research into existing and preferable planning regulations Traffic research Research on underground infrastructure Establish pre-conditions Administrative procedure of the project Preparation of the selection of the architect approving the definitive design (building plan and public space)

11 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT 2549 User Rights Regime I focus on the transaction costs that are caused by the particularities of the user rights regimes. Costs can be attributed to a particular user rights regime when they do not occur in one or more other user rights regimes. To show the regime specificity of the costs, the regime in this case will be briefly compared with alternative regimes. In the development process of Lange- Veerstraat, there are several institutions that relate to the right to use landed property that are similar to the ones shown in Table 1: for example, the sales contract in which the two parties agree upon the exchange of land (and hence the right to use it) and the future uses (see category 3 in Table 1) or the legally binding land use plan in which the right to use is attenuated (see category 2 in Table 1). The activities in this particular land development process that can be attributed to the user rights regime are represented in bold (see Table 2). I discuss them separately and show how they are different from other user rights regimes. In the exploration stage, we hardly find any costs that can be attributed to the user rights regime. Most activities are explorations of the current situation and future possibilities. The only activity is the research into existing and preferable planning regulations. Those costs would not have existed in a regime with no planning regulations at all. An example of this is El Paso County, one of the counties in Texas that border Mexico. In El Paso, there are no zoning, no sub-division, no housing or building codes and no infrastructure requirements (Kushner, 2003, pp ). In El Paso, the user rights regime is only formed by rules from the property rights regime. If in El Paso someone wants to develop a piece of land, he does not need to consult the planning regulations, which saves costs. But, on the other hand, this fails to provide any certainty about how neighbours will use their plot. Negotiation and deliberation with them are then needed to reduce one s uncertainty. Depending on the degree of conflict between the neighbours, this can raise transaction costs significantly. In other words, agents and agencies try to acquire information and reduce uncertainty, one way or another. The costs associated with the different ways can nevertheless vary significantly. The same is true of the distribution of costs. These differences are not only dependent on the regime, but also on the initiating party. In the Dutch case, the municipality took the initiative and acquired most of the land, which led to a situation in which the municipality bears most of the transaction costs (as we can see in Table 2). In England, for instance, local authorities rarely take the initiative and therefore it is often the developers that have to bear the costs of exploring the particular user rights regime. In the plan-making stage, we find most of the costs associated with the user rights regime. In the case study, the municipality acquired most of the land in an amicable way. Compulsory purchase was not possible because at that time the existing land use plan did not provide a legal basis for doing that. Therefore, the municipality was dependent on the willingness of the landowners. Most of the landowners were easily persuaded, but one plot took a long time, because an alternative location had to be found for the owner. Compulsory purchase could have brought matters to a conclusion, but it also has its costs. In the plan-making stage, the bestemmingsplan has been prepared and agreed (which took approximately two years because of an appeal). The bestemmingsplan comprises the whole inner city of Hilversum and not only the project site. Nevertheless, the costs of agreeing the plan can partly be attributed to the project. In an alternative regime, like the English, the amount and the distribution of costs might be different. The plan making of the indicative local plan in England is probably cheaper than the bestemmingsplan, because it is territory-wide, while in the Netherlands the plans are much smaller and legally binding. For instance, in

12 2550 EDWIN BUITELAAR the city of Nijmegen there are approximately 800 bestemmingsplannen, each covering only a small area. However, granting or rejecting a planning permission might involve more transaction costs in England. In England, there is room for negotiation about the content of the planning permission, possibly resulting in a planning agreement, while in the Netherlands an application for a planning permission (see the execution stage) is either granted or not, depending on whether it fits within the plan or not. In addition, the legal certainty the bestemmingsplan provides, reduces uncertainty and transaction costs for the landowners and developers. So, a user rights regime that involves fewer costs at an early point in the development process might, because of that, bring along more costs at a later stage, and vice versa. In El Paso, there are no plan-making costs for the county whatsoever, for there is no plan or anything that comes close to it. However, if there is no plan, there is hardly any certainty for the landowners. The landowners need to acquire information about each others land development intentions individually and cannot rely on a centrally developed plan or other forms of regulation. Another example where the amount and the distribution of transaction costs are different, is in the case of ballot box zoning (see, for example, Staley, 2001). This is a referendum process whereby a development initiative is placed on the ballot for public voting. Although it increases legitimacy, it increases the total transaction costs, which are partly dispersed among the citizens. A counter-reaction can be found in Oregon where the Supreme Court has transformed the zoning system from a political system into an administrative one (Kushner, 2003, p. 231). This should make the zoning process more efficient, from a transaction-cost perspective, but it breaks with the growing concern for citizen participation. Another transaction cost in the plan-making stage in the Dutch project is drawing up the sales agreement. This cost would not have been made (especially by the municipality) if the municipality had not pursued an active land policy. On the other hand, because it did pursue this policy, the municipality was able to impose conditions on the way land was used after the sale. This increased the influence of the municipality. If the municipality had chosen a passive land policy, but nevertheless wanted to keep a grip on the outcome, it would have needed to use other ways, such as persuasion and/or financial conditions, which also involve costs. In other regimes, it is often other parties that enter into agreements. In Houston Texas, for instance, there are thousands of privately established restrictive covenants, besides basic building codes, that govern land use (Siegan, 1970, p. 79). This obviously leads to a different distribution of costs. Other costs in the plan making stage that are mainly incurred by the municipality are costs associated with the administrative process of approving the provisional and definite plan for both the buildings and the public space. In England, deciding upon planning permission usually takes much more time, money and effort than in the Netherlands. In the Dutch bestemmingsplan, many of the spatial trade-offs are made. Granting or rejecting planning permission then is often an administrative procedure. In England, the local plan is indicative and the real trade-off between spatial claims is made in the planning permission stage. If planning permission as in England and the Netherlands was not needed, those costs would not have been necessary. But again, probably different costs, like the costs of signing restrictive covenants (as in Houston) are then needed. But in that case the distribution of costs might be different. The last costs that need to be mentioned are the costs associated with control. Those costs can be called ex-post costs, for they are made after using the user rights regime. After planning permission has been granted, the municipality checks the way a building is being, and has been, built. If there were no planning regulations, there probably would be other transaction costs and a different distribution. For instance, landowner A

13 TRANSACTION COSTS AND DEVELOPMENT 2551 would monitor whether his neighbour, landowner B, builds his house in the way they agreed upon in some contract. If landowner B does not, landowner A can go to court to enforce the contract. In England, most planning permissions are conditional (see, for example, Cullingworth and Nadin, 2002). Conditions might relate to the submission of further design details that have to be approved by the local planning authority, after which the condition is discharged. This can add significantly to the transaction costs. Concluding Comments Transaction costs are used in many texts in a heuristic sense. We get an understanding of what they are and how they affect the allocation of resources, but the practical relevance of the concept often remains unclear. In addition, it is hard to measure transaction costs, because they are numerous and ill-specified. It is therefore not surprising that empirical applications are rare. In this paper, I have put forward a method for identifying transaction costs in concrete development processes that can be found in most capitalist countries. A useful way to identify transaction costs is to distinguish them from the production costs. In a development process with perfect information and no institutions, all the costs that occur are production costs. Such development processes do not exist in the real world, but nevertheless form good points of reference to identify transaction costs. With every activity (in the development process), we can ask whether or not it would have been undertaken in a neo-classical development process. When we know what the transaction costs in a development process are, we can compare ways of co-ordinating the development processes. In the previous section, a comparison between user rights regimes has been made fairly briefly, but it is even more interesting to compare (significantly) different case studies in more detail. Here, I suggest some significantly different case studies that might be worth comparing. First is the case of a Dutch development process which (as we have already seen) is relatively hierarchical in its development control system and is often carried out by an active land policy of the municipality. Another interesting case would be an English case study with more private initiative and a development control system with more room for negotiation. A third case which is significantly different from the previous two, and therefore very interesting, is the case of Houston (Texas). In Houston, we find (unlike almost all other US cities) a non-zoning tradition. Although there is no zoning, it does not mean there is no planning, for the planning department is the biggest planning department of all US cities (Neuman, 2003). The result of such an investigation should be a comparison of the transaction costs of significantly different regimes and a consideration of process efficiency. It probably will not be a conclusion like: the creation and use of regime A is more efficient than that of regime B. A more nuanced analysis could lead to assertions like: in stage X, regime A involves fewer costs than regime B but, in stage Y, it is the other way around. And regime A is more efficient for agency K, while regime B is more efficient for agency L. This will shed a more qualified light than the often-heard argument that the market is more efficient than the government in co-ordinating changes in land use. Notes 1. Land use planning had been approached earlier from a new institutional economic angle by both lawyers (like Ellickson, 1977) and economists (like Fischel, 1978), but their attempts received little attention from planning theorists. 2. Healey defines land development processes as the transformation of the physical form, bundle of rights, and material and symbolic value of land and buildings from one state to another, through the effort of agents with interests and purposes in acquiring and using resources, operating rules and applying and developing ideas and values (Healey, 1992, p. 36).

14 2552 EDWIN BUITELAAR 3. Although the analogy with the production process is made, I do not intend to focus on capital flows and their determining role in the development process, and human interaction in general, as in many Marxist production-based models of the development process (see Gore and Nicholson, 1991; Healey, 1991). The analogy simply emphasises the supply side of development. In addition, production-based models hardly take account of the role of institutions; as will become clear, this paper does. 4. If the agency costs of making a product are perceived to be high or too high a company might decide to hive-off that activity. 5. Sometimes, creation and use coincide. For instance, with designing the Town and Country Planning Act in the UK in 1947, the development plan as an institution was created. If the local government makes a development plan it uses the Town and Country Planning Act and at the same time creates local rules that have to be taken into account when planning permission is decided upon. 6. Thompson et al. (1991) distinguish between three models of co-ordination: market, hierarchy and network. I have applied these three models to land use planning (Buitelaar, 2003). In general, it comes down to the assumption that in markets it is the price mechanism that co-ordinates, whereas in hierarchical forms it is command-and-control and, in network forms, collaboration that play a central role. 7. There are also people (like Bromley, 1991, p. 83) who argue that the term social costs is incorrect and that most of the negative externalities are individual costs. 8. Coase (1960, see also, for example, Eggertsson, 1990, pp ) argues that the distribution of resources i.e. the initial assignment of property rights does not matter, in a situation when the property rights are clearly delineated and there are no transaction costs associated. This thesis became famous as the Coase theorem. Coase introduced the notions of institutions, in particular property rights, and transaction costs. Although this has been a major shift in the welfare economic paradigm, Coase s goal was, like the traditional welfare economists (such as Pigou), allocative or output efficiency. Therefore, Coase can also be called a welfare economist. 9. North (1990a, p. 17) argues that, although hardly any economists believe that the behavioural assumptions reflect human behaviour, they do build many of their models upon those assumptions. 10. I must add to this that the change and use of institutions do not only give rise to the transaction costs, but can also increase the production costs. For instance, the application of some environmental act might require soil decontamination. These costs are production costs, but do not exist in a neo-classical market. So, transaction costs are the costs (other than the production costs) that would not exist in a neo-classical market, not being the costs of the physical production of the built environment. I will give no further attention to the latter costs. 11. The bundle of rights consists of the right to use (usus), the right to income (usus fructus) and the right to transfer (abusus) (see de Alessi, 1991). The right to use a piece of land (i.e. the user rights over that land), and the restrictions upon it, are of particular interest to land use planning. 12. It should be noted that, because a price has to be paid for a piece of land (like any other good), it suggests that there is an institution like private property, while a neo-classical market is supposed to be institutionless. References ALESSI,L.DE (1991) Development of the property right approach, in: E. G. FURUBOTN and R. RICHTER (Eds) The New Institutional Economics: A Collection of Articles from the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, pp Tübingen: Mohr. ALEXANDER, E. R.(1992) A transaction cost theory of planning, Journal of the American Planning Association, 58, pp ALEXANDER, E. R.(2001a) A transaction-cost theory of land use planning and development control; toward the institutional analysis of public planning, Town Planning Review, 72, pp ALEXANDER, E. R.(2001b) Why planning vs. markets is an oxymoron: asking the right question, Planning and Markets, 4 (on-line journal). BALL, M.(1998) Institutions in British property research: a review, Urban Studies, 35, pp BROMLEY, D. W.(1991) Environment and Economy: Property Rights and Public Policy. Oxford: Blackwell. BUITELAAR, E.(2003) Neither market nor government: comparing the performance of user rights regimes, Town Planning Review, 74, pp BUITELAAR, E., JACOBS, W. and LAGENDIJK, A. (2004) Institutional change in spatial governance: illustrated by Dutch city-regions and Dutch land policy. Paper presented at the GaP Congress Mind the GaP: The governance of

CLTS seminar 24 January 2014

CLTS seminar 24 January 2014 Workshop International perspective on property right regimes Department of Landscape Architecture and Spatial Planning Section of Land Management Norwegian University of Life Science Norway Dr Barbara

More information

A Property Rights Approach to Externality Problems: Planning Based on Compensation Rules

A Property Rights Approach to Externality Problems: Planning Based on Compensation Rules 46(13) 2869 2890, December 2009 A Property Rights Approach to Externality Problems: Planning Based on Compensation Rules Erwin van der Krabben [Paper first received, June 2007; in final form, October 2008]

More information

The Ethics and Economics of Private Property

The Ethics and Economics of Private Property Hans-Hermann Hoppe The Ethics and Economics of Private Property [excerpted from chapter in a forthcoming book] V. Chicago Diversions At the time when Rothbard was restoring the concept of private property

More information

THINKING OUTSIDE THE TRIANGLE TAKING ADVANTAGE OF MODERN LAND MARKETS. Ian Williamson

THINKING OUTSIDE THE TRIANGLE TAKING ADVANTAGE OF MODERN LAND MARKETS. Ian Williamson THINKING OUTSIDE THE TRIANGLE TAKING ADVANTAGE OF MODERN LAND MARKETS Ian Williamson Professor of Surveying and Land Information Head, Department of Geomatics Director, Centre for Spatial Data Infrastructures

More information

Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB)

Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) Leases Exposure Draft ED/2013/6, issued by the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) Comments from ACCA 13 September 2013 ACCA (the Association of Chartered Certified Accountants) is the global

More information

Agreements for the Construction of Real Estate

Agreements for the Construction of Real Estate HK(IFRIC)-Int 15 Revised August 2010September 2018 Effective for annual periods beginning on or after 1 January 2009* HK(IFRIC) Interpretation 15 Agreements for the Construction of Real Estate * HK(IFRIC)-Int

More information

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. Durability and Monopoly Author(s): R. H. Coase Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1 (Apr., 1972), pp. 143-149 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/725018

More information

Real Estate Development Agreements in Sweden

Real Estate Development Agreements in Sweden Real Estate Development Agreements in Sweden Maria ULFVARSON ÖSTLUND, Sweden Key words:, commitments, implementation, management, planning, urban. SUMMARY Land management or management of also means of

More information

Securing Land Rights for Broadband Land Acquisition for Utilities in Sweden

Securing Land Rights for Broadband Land Acquisition for Utilities in Sweden Securing Land Rights for Broadband Land Acquisition for Utilities in Sweden Marija JURIC and Kristin LAND, Sweden Key words: broadband, land acquisition, cadastral procedure, Sweden SUMMARY The European

More information

Viability and the Planning System: The Relationship between Economic Viability Testing, Land Values and Affordable Housing in London

Viability and the Planning System: The Relationship between Economic Viability Testing, Land Values and Affordable Housing in London Viability and the Planning System: The Relationship between Economic Viability Testing, Land Values and Affordable Housing in London Executive Summary & Key Findings A changed planning environment in which

More information

Easements, Covenants and Profits à Prendre Executive Summary

Easements, Covenants and Profits à Prendre Executive Summary Easements, Covenants and Profits à Prendre Executive Summary Consultation Paper No 186 (Summary) 28 March 2008 EASEMENTS, COVENANTS AND PROFITS À PRENDRE: A CONSULTATION PAPER EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 1.1 This

More information

Institutional Analysis of Condominium Management System in Amhara Region: the Case of Bahir Dar City

Institutional Analysis of Condominium Management System in Amhara Region: the Case of Bahir Dar City Institutional Analysis of Condominium Management System in Amhara Region: the Case of Bahir Dar City Zelalem Yirga Institute of Land Administration Bahir Dar University, Ethiopia Session agenda: Construction

More information

IFA submission to the Law Reform Commission of Ireland s review of the current law on compulsory acquisition of land.

IFA submission to the Law Reform Commission of Ireland s review of the current law on compulsory acquisition of land. IFA submission to the Law Reform Commission of Ireland s review of the current law on compulsory acquisition of land. The Irish Farm Centre Bluebell Dublin 12 February 2018 Introduction The Issues Paper

More information

Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property

Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property Chapter 4 An Economic Theory of Property I. Introduction From an economic perspective, we are interested in how property law influences the allocation of scarce resources and goods and services. An important

More information

Sincerity Among Landlords & Tenants

Sincerity Among Landlords & Tenants Sincerity Among Landlords & Tenants By Mark Alexander, founder of "The Landlords Union" Several people who are looking to rent a property want to stay for the long term, especially when they have children

More information

Easy Legals Avoiding the costly mistakes most people make when buying a property including buyer s checklist

Easy Legals Avoiding the costly mistakes most people make when buying a property including buyer s checklist Easy Legals Avoiding the costly mistakes most people make when buying a property including buyer s checklist Our Experience is Your Advantage 1. Why is this guide important? Thank you for ordering this

More information

ICBA RESPONSE TO RELAXATION OF PLANNING RULES FOR CHANGE OF USE FROM COMMERCIAL TO RESIDENTIAL CONSULTATION

ICBA RESPONSE TO RELAXATION OF PLANNING RULES FOR CHANGE OF USE FROM COMMERCIAL TO RESIDENTIAL CONSULTATION ICBA RESPONSE TO RELAXATION OF PLANNING RULES FOR CHANGE OF USE FROM COMMERCIAL TO RESIDENTIAL CONSULTATION Question A Do you support the principle of the Government s proposal to grant permitted development

More information

Papers The Digital Economy Act : What surveyors need to know about changes to the law on telecommunications equipment

Papers The Digital Economy Act : What surveyors need to know about changes to the law on telecommunications equipment Journal of Building Survey, Appraisal & Valuation Volume 6 Number 3 Papers The Digital Economy Act : What surveyors need to know about changes to the law on telecommunications equipment Michael Watson

More information

WHAT IS AN APPROPRIATE CADASTRAL SYSTEM IN AFRICA?

WHAT IS AN APPROPRIATE CADASTRAL SYSTEM IN AFRICA? WHAT IS AN APPROPRIATE CADASTRAL SYSTEM IN AFRICA? Tommy ÖSTERBERG, Sweden Key words: ABSTRACT The following discussion is based on my experiences from working with cadastral issues in some African countries

More information

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION Chapter 35 The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION The most commonly used appraisal technique is the sales comparison approach. The fundamental concept underlying this approach is that market

More information

Assessment of mass valuation methodology for compensation in the land reform process in Albania

Assessment of mass valuation methodology for compensation in the land reform process in Albania 1 Assessment of mass valuation methodology for compensation in the land reform process in Albania Fatbardh Sallaku Agricultural University of Tirana, Department of AgroEnvironmental & Ecology Agim Shehu

More information

Review of the Plaistow and Ifold Site Options and Assessment Report Issued by AECOM in August 2016.

Review of the Plaistow and Ifold Site Options and Assessment Report Issued by AECOM in August 2016. Review of the Plaistow and Ifold Site Options and Assessment Report Issued by AECOM in August 2016. Our ref: CHI/16/01 Prepared by Colin Smith Planning Ltd September 2016 1.0 INTRODUCTION 1.1 Colin Smith

More information

CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS

CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS CENTRAL GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING STANDARDS NOVEMBER 2016 STANDARD 4 Requirements STANDARD 5 INTANGIBLE ASSETS INTRODUCTION... 75 I. CENTRAL GOVERNMENT S SPECIALISED ASSETS... 75 I.1. The collection of sovereign

More information

Re: Proposed Accounting Standards Update, Applying Variable Interest Entity Guidance to Common Control Leasing Arrangements

Re: Proposed Accounting Standards Update, Applying Variable Interest Entity Guidance to Common Control Leasing Arrangements Financial Reporting Advisors, LLC 100 North LaSalle Street, Suite 2215 Chicago, Illinois 60602 312.345.9101 www.finra.com VIA EMAIL TO: director@fasb.org Technical Director File Reference No. PCC-13-02

More information

SCOTTISH GOVERNMENT RESPONSE TO PRIVATE RENTED HOUSING (SCOTLAND) BILL STAGE 1 REPORT

SCOTTISH GOVERNMENT RESPONSE TO PRIVATE RENTED HOUSING (SCOTLAND) BILL STAGE 1 REPORT SCOTTISH GOVERNMENT RESPONSE TO PRIVATE RENTED HOUSING (SCOTLAND) BILL STAGE 1 REPORT I am writing in response to the Local Government and Communities Committee s Stage 1 Report on the Private Rented Housing

More information

CLTS seminar 24 januar The Role of State versus Market in Land for Housing in Urban Areas in Nordic Countries

CLTS seminar 24 januar The Role of State versus Market in Land for Housing in Urban Areas in Nordic Countries The Role of State versus Market in Land for Housing in Urban Areas in Nordic Countries Berit Nordahl, Ås 24 th of January 2014 Tittel på presentasjon Norwegian University of Life Sciences 2 1 Models of

More information

Oil & Gas Lease Auctions: An Economic Perspective

Oil & Gas Lease Auctions: An Economic Perspective Oil & Gas Lease Auctions: An Economic Perspective March 15, 2010 Presented by: The Florida Legislature Office of Economic and Demographic Research 850.487.1402 http://edr.state.fl.us Bidding for Oil &

More information

Factsheet 2. Good practice and factors for consideration in England and Wales

Factsheet 2. Good practice and factors for consideration in England and Wales Good practice and factors for consideration in England and Wales This factsheet is intended to help resolve some of the questions that arise in relation to disability-related alterations to common parts

More information

Proposal to Restructure

Proposal to Restructure ~ Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Date: November 10,2008 Country: Ukraine Project Name: Rural Land Titling and Cadastre

More information

Cadastral Template 2003

Cadastral Template 2003 PCGIAP-Working Group 3 "Cadastre" FIG-Commission 7 "Cadastre and Land Management" Cadastral Template 2003 The establishment of a cadastral template is one of the objectives of Working Group 3 "Cadastre"

More information

.01 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment for investment property and related disclosure requirements.

.01 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment for investment property and related disclosure requirements. COMPARISON OF GRAP 16 WITH IAS 40 GRAP 16 IAS 40 DIFFERENCES Objective.01 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe the accounting treatment for investment property and related disclosure requirements.

More information

MARKET VALUE BASIS OF VALUATION

MARKET VALUE BASIS OF VALUATION 4.2 INTERNATIONAL VALUATION STANDARDS 1 MARKET VALUE BASIS OF VALUATION This Standard should be read in the context of the background material and implementation guidance contained in General Valuation

More information

PLANNING & BUILDING REGULATIONS

PLANNING & BUILDING REGULATIONS SCANDIA-HUS FACT SHEET NO. 10 PLANNING & BUILDING REGULATIONS DATE: 1 ST JANUARY 2018 ISSUE NO: 4 THE PLANNING SYSTEM Scandia-Hus will, as part of the service, handle all aspects of design, planning and

More information

The capitalization rate is essential to any analysis through the income

The capitalization rate is essential to any analysis through the income FEATURES An Argument for Establishing a Standard Method of Capitalization Derivation by Eric T. Reenstierna, MAI The capitalization rate is essential to any analysis through the income capitalization approach.

More information

Proposals for Best Practice

Proposals for Best Practice WPLA Fees & Charges in Cadastre and Registration Proposals for Best Practice Neil King United Kingdom WPLA Fees and Charges Study Best Practice This presentation offers an overview of a draft report that

More information

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Mark Livingston, Nick Bailey and Christina Boididou UBDC April 2018 Introduction The private rental sector (PRS)

More information

Affordable Housing in the Draft National Planning Policy Framework

Affordable Housing in the Draft National Planning Policy Framework Affordable Housing in the Draft National Planning Policy Framework Introduction 1. The draft National Planning Policy Framework (NPPF) proposes to cancel Planning Policy Statement 3 (PPS3) Housing (2005

More information

Housing Authority Models FIRST NATION MODELS: COMPARITIVE REPORT

Housing Authority Models FIRST NATION MODELS: COMPARITIVE REPORT Housing Authority Models FIRST NATION MODELS: COMPARITIVE REPORT Assembly of First Nations May 2012 TABLE OF CONTENTS FIRST NATION MODELS: COMPARITIVE REPORT...1 (1) HOUSING COMMITTEE ESTABLISHED BY CHIEF

More information

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 11.433J / 15.021J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms. Recitation 9 Real

More information

Benchmarking Cadastral Systems Results of the Working Group 7.1

Benchmarking Cadastral Systems Results of the Working Group 7.1 Benchmarking Cadastral Systems Results of the Working Group 7.1 Jürg KAUFMANN, Switzerland Key words: ABSTRACT In 1998, FIG-Commission 7 launched three new working groups for the period 1998-2002. Working

More information

ISSUES OF EFFICIENCY IN PUBLIC REAL ESTATE RESOURCES MANAGEMENT

ISSUES OF EFFICIENCY IN PUBLIC REAL ESTATE RESOURCES MANAGEMENT Alina Zrobek-Rozanska (MSC) Prof. Ryszard Zrobek University of Warmia and Mazury in Olsztyn, Poland rzrobek@uwm.edu.pl alina.zrobek@uwm.edu.pl ISSUES OF EFFICIENCY IN PUBLIC REAL ESTATE RESOURCES MANAGEMENT

More information

Intangibles CHAPTER CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to:

Intangibles CHAPTER CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to: CHAPTER Intangibles CHAPTER OBJECTIVES After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to: 1. Explain the accounting alternatives for intangibles. 2. Record the amortization or impairment of intangibles.

More information

Key findings from an investigation into low- and medium-value property sales. National Audit Office September 2017 DP

Key findings from an investigation into low- and medium-value property sales. National Audit Office September 2017 DP from an investigation into low- and medium-value property sales National Audit Office September 207 DP 557-00 from an investigation into low- and medium-value property sales Contents 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 2

More information

Acquisition of investment properties asset purchase or business combination?

Acquisition of investment properties asset purchase or business combination? Acquisition of investment properties asset purchase or business combination? Our IFRS Viewpoint series provides insights from our global IFRS team on applying IFRSs in challenging situations. Each edition

More information

Introduction of a Land Registry service delivery company

Introduction of a Land Registry service delivery company Introduction of a Land Registry service delivery company Response by the Council of Mortgage Lenders to the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills Introduction 1. The CML is the representative

More information

A Conveyancer s Lot Post P&P Property and Dreamvar

A Conveyancer s Lot Post P&P Property and Dreamvar A Conveyancer s Lot Post P&P Property and Dreamvar June 2018 Jason Nash Partner, BLM T +44 (0)161 838 6953 E Jason.nash@blmlaw.com The spotlight has never been so bright on the world of conveyancing as

More information

Rohan Bennett (PhD) Jaap Zevenbergen (Prof.)

Rohan Bennett (PhD) Jaap Zevenbergen (Prof.) Developing an integrated conceptual model to understand land governance continuum Berhanu K. Alemie (PhD) Rohan Bennett (PhD) Jaap Zevenbergen (Prof.) Presentation outline Background Research objective

More information

Guidelines for the Consideration of Applications for the Demolition or Moving of Structures Within the Northville Historic District

Guidelines for the Consideration of Applications for the Demolition or Moving of Structures Within the Northville Historic District Guidelines for the Consideration of Applications for the Demolition or Moving of Structures Within the Northville Historic District A. RESPONSIBILITY OF THE HISTORIC DISTRICT COMMISSION The Northville

More information

we apply for the necessary searches you make your mortgage application (if applicable)

we apply for the necessary searches you make your mortgage application (if applicable) NOTES FOR BUYERS These notes contain important information about buying a property, and we ask you to read through them carefully. They form an integral part of our conveyancing service, and we hope that

More information

FOR INFORMATION PURPOSES ONLY. Request for Proposals for the Purchase of a Site for the New Acute Care Hospital with Schedules

FOR INFORMATION PURPOSES ONLY. Request for Proposals for the Purchase of a Site for the New Acute Care Hospital with Schedules FOR INFORMATION PURPOSES ONLY Request for Proposals for the Purchase of a Site for the New Acute Care Hospital with Schedules Request for Proposals for the Purchase of a Site for the New Acute Care Hospital

More information

Heathrow Expansion. Land Acquisition and Compensation Policies. Interim Property Hardship Scheme. Policy Terms

Heathrow Expansion. Land Acquisition and Compensation Policies. Interim Property Hardship Scheme. Policy Terms 1 Introduction Heathrow Expansion Land Acquisition and Compensation Policies Interim Property Hardship Scheme Policy Terms 1.1 This document sets out the terms of the Interim Property Hardship Scheme (the

More information

Accounting Of Intangible Assets Indian as- 26

Accounting Of Intangible Assets Indian as- 26 IOSR Journal of Business and Management (IOSR-JBM) e-issn: 2278-487X, p-issn: 2319-7668. Volume 16, Issue 2. Ver. II (Feb. 2014), PP 40-45 Accounting Of Intangible Assets Indian as- 26 Manpreet Sharma,

More information

OPINION OF SENIOR COUNSEL FOR GLASGOW ADVICE AGENCY (HOUSING BENEFIT AMENDMENTS

OPINION OF SENIOR COUNSEL FOR GLASGOW ADVICE AGENCY (HOUSING BENEFIT AMENDMENTS OPINION OF SENIOR COUNSEL FOR GLASGOW ADVICE AGENCY (HOUSING BENEFIT AMENDMENTS 1. By email instructions of 9 February 2013, I am asked for my opinion on questions relative to the imminent introduction

More information

WORKSHOP Five Year Housing Supply and Calculating Housing Needs

WORKSHOP Five Year Housing Supply and Calculating Housing Needs WORKSHOP Five Year Housing Supply and Calculating Housing Needs Robert Love Senior Planner - Bidwells Roland Bolton Senior Director - DLP Planning Limited/SPRU Organisation of Workshop 79 people Form 12

More information

Law on Housing and Maintenance of Apartment

Law on Housing and Maintenance of Apartment Law on Housing and Maintenance of Apartment Buildings Law on Housing and Maintenance of Apartment Buildings The rights and obligations of people who live in apartment buildings, maintenance of apartment

More information

Use of Comparables. Claims Prevention Bulletin [CP-17-E] March 1996

Use of Comparables. Claims Prevention Bulletin [CP-17-E] March 1996 March 1996 The use of comparables arises almost daily for all appraisers. especially those engaged in residential practice, where appraisals are being prepared for mortgage underwriting purposes. That

More information

MAKING THE MOST EFFECTIVE AND SUSTAINABLE USE OF LAND

MAKING THE MOST EFFECTIVE AND SUSTAINABLE USE OF LAND 165 SOC146 To deliver places that are more sustainable, development will make the most effective and sustainable use of land, focusing on: Housing density Reusing previously developed land Bringing empty

More information

A Study of Experiment in Architecture with Reference to Personalised Houses

A Study of Experiment in Architecture with Reference to Personalised Houses 6 th International Conference on Structural Engineering and Construction Management 2015, Kandy, Sri Lanka, 11 th -13 th December 2015 SECM/15/001 A Study of Experiment in Architecture with Reference to

More information

South Worcestershire Development Plan Examination Representation Form Additional Pages Consultation on Proposed Modifications to SWDP: 6 October 14 November 2014 South Worcestershire Councils Additional

More information

ECON 522- SECTION 4- INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, FUGITIVE PROP- 1. Intellectual Property. 2. Adverse Possession. 3. Fugitive Property

ECON 522- SECTION 4- INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, FUGITIVE PROP- 1. Intellectual Property. 2. Adverse Possession. 3. Fugitive Property ECON 522- SECTION 4- INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, FUGITIVE PROP- ERTY, AND EXTENSIVE FORM GAMES 1. Intellectual Property Intellectual property rights take goods which seem to fit the definition of a public good:

More information

WHITE PAPER. New Lease Accounting Rules

WHITE PAPER. New Lease Accounting Rules WHITE PAPER New Lease Accounting Rules WHITE PAPER Introduction New lease accounting rules (FASB Topic 842) will be required for all public companies beginning in 2019. The primary goal of the new standard

More information

Determining whether an Arrangement contains a Lease

Determining whether an Arrangement contains a Lease IFRIC 4 IFRIC Interpretation 4 Determining whether an Arrangement contains a Lease This version includes amendments resulting from IFRSs issued up to 31 December 2008. IFRIC 4 Determining whether an Arrangement

More information

Rotorua Air Quality Control Bylaw

Rotorua Air Quality Control Bylaw Rotorua Air Quality Control Bylaw Administration and Enforcement Strategy Strategic Policy Publication 2011/04 ISSN 1176 4112 (print) ISSN 1178 3907 (online) September 2011 Bay of Plenty Regional Council

More information

Private Housing (Tenancies) (Scotland) Bill. Written submission to the Infrastructure and Capital investment Committee

Private Housing (Tenancies) (Scotland) Bill. Written submission to the Infrastructure and Capital investment Committee Private Housing (Tenancies) (Scotland) Bill Written submission to the Infrastructure and Capital investment Committee Background: The National Landlords Association (NLA) The National Landlords Association

More information

Assets of Community Value under the Localism Act - Blighting of development or boosting the local community. Christopher Cant

Assets of Community Value under the Localism Act - Blighting of development or boosting the local community. Christopher Cant Assets of Community Value under the Localism Act - Blighting of development or boosting the local community Christopher Cant This government appears unable to make up its mind as to whether it really wishes

More information

10 April But rarely is this the position in practice.

10 April But rarely is this the position in practice. Bank Guarantees 10 April 2014 Most construction contracts for large scale infrastructure and commercial projects require contractors to provide a principal with an unconditional bank guarantee to secure

More information

NORTH LEEDS MATTER 2. Response to Leeds Sites and Allocations DPD Examination Inspector s Questions. August 2017

NORTH LEEDS MATTER 2. Response to Leeds Sites and Allocations DPD Examination Inspector s Questions. August 2017 NORTH LEEDS MATTER 2 Response to Leeds Sites and Allocations DPD Examination Inspector s Questions August 2017 CLIENT: TAYLOR WIMPEY, ADEL REFERENCE NO: CONTENTS 1.0 INTRODUCTION 2.0 TEST OF SOUNDNESS

More information

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Explanatory note

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Explanatory note EUROPEAN COMMISSION Competition DG Explanatory note Best Practice Guidelines: The Commission's Model Texts for Divestiture Commitments and the Trustee Mandate under the EC Merger Regulation 5 December

More information

Landlord s Checklist Of Silent Lease Issues (Second Edition)

Landlord s Checklist Of Silent Lease Issues (Second Edition) Landlord s Checklist Of Silent Lease Issues (Second Edition) By Landlord s Silent Lease Issues Subcommittee, Commercial Leasing Committee, Real Property Law Section, New York State Bar Association; S.H.

More information

I am writing on behalf of leading European retail companies represented in the European Retail Round Table (ERRT).

I am writing on behalf of leading European retail companies represented in the European Retail Round Table (ERRT). -.. : European Retail Round Table 2013-270 International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) IFRS Foundation Publications Department 1st Floor, 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom Copy: European

More information

Chapter 3: A Framework for a National Land Information Infrastructure

Chapter 3: A Framework for a National Land Information Infrastructure Chapter 3: A Framework for a National Land Information Infrastructure Brian Marwick Overview As a federated county, Australia s land administration systems are state and territory based. These systems,

More information

Do You Want to Buy a Home but have Poor Credit or Little in Savings?

Do You Want to Buy a Home but have Poor Credit or Little in Savings? Do You Want to Buy a Home but have Poor Credit or Little in Savings? If you re reading this guide, you re likely considering rent to own (also commonly referred to as lease to own ) properties because

More information

Research report Tenancy sustainment in Scotland

Research report Tenancy sustainment in Scotland Research report Tenancy sustainment in Scotland From the Shelter policy library October 2009 www.shelter.org.uk 2009 Shelter. All rights reserved. This document is only for your personal, non-commercial

More information

BOUNDARIES & SQUATTER S RIGHTS

BOUNDARIES & SQUATTER S RIGHTS BOUNDARIES & SQUATTER S RIGHTS Odd Results? The general boundary rule can have results that seem odd - for example the Land Registry s Practice Guides make it clear that they may regard you as owning land

More information

ASSESSMENT OF CONSEQUENCES RESULTING FROM ABOLISHING THE OBSTACLES ON LAND TRANSACTIONS 1 SUMMARY

ASSESSMENT OF CONSEQUENCES RESULTING FROM ABOLISHING THE OBSTACLES ON LAND TRANSACTIONS 1 SUMMARY ASSESSMENT OF CONSEQUENCES RESULTING FROM ABOLISHING THE OBSTACLES ON LAND TRANSACTIONS 1 SUMMARY I. Foreign practice in regulation of land market and the EU legal provisions Having analysed the existing

More information

property even if the parties have no lease arrangement. This is often called an option contract.

property even if the parties have no lease arrangement. This is often called an option contract. In the farming community, lease-to-own refers to certain methods to achieve land ownership. Purchasing a farm with conventional financing is simply not an option (or the best option) for many. Lease-to-own

More information

Member consultation: Rent freedom

Member consultation: Rent freedom November 2016 Member consultation: Rent freedom The future of housing association rents Summary of key points: Housing associations are ambitious socially driven organisations currently exploring new ways

More information

The Housing, Communities and Local Government Committee. The effectiveness of current land value capture methods

The Housing, Communities and Local Government Committee. The effectiveness of current land value capture methods The Housing, Communities and Local Government Committee The effectiveness of current land value capture methods Submission made by the Executive Summary 1. This submission represents the views of the national

More information

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights.

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights. 7. Property Rights and Externalities 7.1 Introduction First fundamental theorem of welfare economics requires well defined property rights. Property rights: a bundle of entitlements defining the owner

More information

CONTACT(S) Raghava Tirumala +44 (0) Woung Hee Lee +44 (0)

CONTACT(S) Raghava Tirumala +44 (0) Woung Hee Lee +44 (0) IASB Agenda ref 18A STAFF PAPER IASB Meeting Project Paper topic Goodwill and Impairment research project Summary of discussions to date CONTACT(S) Raghava Tirumala rtirumala@ifrs.org +44 (0)20 7246 6953

More information

HKFRS 15. How the new standard affects revenue recognition of Hong Kong real estate sales before completion

HKFRS 15. How the new standard affects revenue recognition of Hong Kong real estate sales before completion Source Technical update HKFRS 15 How the new standard affects revenue recognition of Hong Kong real estate sales before completion Introduction HKFRS 15 Revenue from Contracts with Customers was issued

More information

Real Estate Institute of New Zealand (REINZ) Submission on the Draft AML/CFT Amendment Bill (Draft Bill)

Real Estate Institute of New Zealand (REINZ) Submission on the Draft AML/CFT Amendment Bill (Draft Bill) 20 April 2017 Parliamentary Select Committee AML/CFT Amendment Bill Dear Committee Real Estate Institute of New Zealand (REINZ) Submission on the Draft AML/CFT Amendment Bill (Draft Bill) REINZ is grateful

More information

Regulatory Impact Statement

Regulatory Impact Statement Regulatory Impact Statement Establishing one new special housing area in Queenstown under the Housing Accords and Special Housing Areas Act 2013. Agency Disclosure Statement 1 This Regulatory Impact Statement

More information

Architects Accreditation Council of Australia New Zealand Institute of Architects (Inc) New Zealand Ministry for Business, Innovation and Employment

Architects Accreditation Council of Australia New Zealand Institute of Architects (Inc) New Zealand Ministry for Business, Innovation and Employment From: To: CC: Subject: New Zealand Registered Architects Board Australian Productivity Commission mutual.recognition@pc.gov.au Architects Accreditation Council of Australia New Zealand Institute of Architects

More information

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale Athanasia Karakitsiou 2, Athanasia Mavrommati 1,3 2 Department of Business Administration, Educational Techological Institute of Serres,

More information

Topic 842 Technical Corrections Summary of Comments Received

Topic 842 Technical Corrections Summary of Comments Received Contact(s) David Hoyer Co-Author Ext. 462 Andy Bologna Co-Author Ext. 356 Thomas Faineteau Co-Author Ext. 362 Chris Roberge Co-Author Ext. 274 Amy Park Co-Author Ext. 476 Shayne Kuhaneck Assistant Director

More information

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 29.11.2008 EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARD 3 Business combinations OBJECTIVE 1 The objective of this IFRS is to specify the financial reporting

More information

Ownership Data in Cadastral Information System of Sofia (CIS Sofia) from the Available Cadastral Map

Ownership Data in Cadastral Information System of Sofia (CIS Sofia) from the Available Cadastral Map Ownership Data in Cadastral Information System of Sofia (CIS Sofia) from the Available Cadastral Map Key words: ABSTRACT Lydmila LAZAROVA, Bulgaria CIS Sofia is created and maintained by GIS Sofia ltd,

More information

CONTACT(S) Annamaria Frosi +44 (0) Rachel Knubley +44 (0)

CONTACT(S) Annamaria Frosi +44 (0) Rachel Knubley +44 (0) IASB Agenda ref 11 STAFF PAPER IASB Meeting Project Paper topic Materiality Practice Statement Sweep issues covenants CONTACT(S) Annamaria Frosi afrosi@ifrs.org +44 (0)20 7246 6907 Rachel Knubley rknubley@ifrs.org

More information

31 July 2014 Japan s Modified International Standards (JMIS): Accounting Standards Comprising IFRSs and the ASBJ Modifications

31 July 2014 Japan s Modified International Standards (JMIS): Accounting Standards Comprising IFRSs and the ASBJ Modifications 31 July 2014 Japan s Modified International Standards (JMIS): Accounting Standards Comprising IFRSs and the ASBJ Modifications ASBJ Modification Accounting Standard Exposure Draft No. 1 Accounting for

More information

AVA. Accredited Valuation Analyst - AVA Exam.

AVA. Accredited Valuation Analyst - AVA Exam. NACVA AVA Accredited Valuation Analyst - AVA Exam TYPE: DEMO http://www.examskey.com/ava.html Examskey NACVA AVA exam demo product is here for you to test the quality of the product. This NACVA AVA demo

More information

Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis

Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal Apartment Cleaning by Harried College Students: A Game-Theoretic Analysis Amitrajeet Batabyal Department of Economics, Rochester Institute of Technology 12 June

More information

Limited Partnerships - Planning for the Future

Limited Partnerships - Planning for the Future Limited Partnerships - Planning for the Future Recommended Guidance for Limited and General Partners published jointly by the National Farmers Union of Scotland Scottish Land and Estates Scottish Tenant

More information

Policy briefing: Avoiding unnecessary evictions among social tenants in Wales

Policy briefing: Avoiding unnecessary evictions among social tenants in Wales Policy briefing: Avoiding unnecessary evictions among social tenants in Wales September 2018 Introduction This paper sets out the case for raising minimum standards in the way in which social landlords

More information

A Guide to Lease Extensions for the Barbican Estate

A Guide to Lease Extensions for the Barbican Estate A Guide to Lease Extensions for the Barbican Estate Under the Leasehold and Urban Development Act 1993 (as amended) ( the Act ) Barbican Long Leaseholders may purchase a new Lease from the City of London

More information

Leases (Topic 842) Proposed Accounting Standards Update. Narrow-Scope Improvements for Lessors

Leases (Topic 842) Proposed Accounting Standards Update. Narrow-Scope Improvements for Lessors Proposed Accounting Standards Update Issued: August 13, 2018 Comments Due: September 12, 2018 Leases (Topic 842) Narrow-Scope Improvements for Lessors The Board issued this Exposure Draft to solicit public

More information

ASSET TRANSFER REQUESTS Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015 Guidance Notes

ASSET TRANSFER REQUESTS Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015 Guidance Notes www.hie.co.uk ASSET TRANSFER REQUESTS Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015 Guidance Notes January 2017 CONTENTS ABOUT THIS GUIDANCE 3 INTRODUCTION 4 About Highlands and Islands Enterprise 4 HIE s

More information

Applying IFRS. A closer look at the new leases standard. August 2016

Applying IFRS. A closer look at the new leases standard. August 2016 Applying IFRS A closer look at the new leases standard August 2016 Contents Overview 3 1. Scope and scope exceptions 5 1.1 General 5 1.2 Determining whether an arrangement contains a lease 6 1.3 Identifying

More information

21 August Mr Hans Hoogervorst Chairman International Accounting Standards Board 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom

21 August Mr Hans Hoogervorst Chairman International Accounting Standards Board 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom 21 August 2013 Mr Hans Hoogervorst Chairman International Accounting Standards Board 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH United Kingdom Via online submission: www.ifrs.org Dear Hans ED 2013/6: Leases Thank

More information

Fulfilment of the contract depends on the use of an identified asset; and

Fulfilment of the contract depends on the use of an identified asset; and ANNEXE ANSWERS TO SPECIFIC QUESTIONS Question 1: identifying a lease This revised Exposure Draft defines a lease as a contract that conveys the right to use an asset (the underlying asset) for a period

More information