Resource Allocation to Housing Inves+mnent: Comments and Further Results. The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Resource Allocation to Housing Inves+mnent: Comments and Further Results. The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea"

Transcription

1 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized World Bank Reprint Series: Number 183 Bertrand Renaud Resource Allocation to Housing Inves+mnent: Comments and Further Results The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea (with James Follain and Gill-Chin Lim) Determinants of Home Ownership in a Developing Economy: The Case of Korea (with Gill-Chin Lim and James Follain) Reprinted with permission from Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 28, no. 2 (January 1980), pp , copyrighted by the University of Chicago; Journal of Urban Economics, vol. 7 (1980), pp ; and Urban Studies, vol. 17 (1980), pp

2 Resource Allocation to Housing Investment: Comments and Further Results* In a recent paper, Burns and Grebler (B-G) presented one of the first systematic investigations of the place that investment in residential construction occupies in the total output of an economy at various levels of development., Their analysis is particularly welcome because of the frequent lack of realism observed in formulating housing plans. Burns and Grebler show that there is a systematic nonlinear relationship between investment in residential construction and the per capita output of a country. This relationship is sufficiently stable and precise that one may ask under what condition their findings can be used as a norm. The te:m ''norm" is used here in the sense of a simplified procedure capable of producing meaningful orders of magnitude to gauge planned levels of housing investment in an economy, before proceeding inito a detailed analysis of the housing sector. To establish the conceptual foundations of their atnalysis, B-G reviewed three types of arguments concerning the proper size of housing in total output. First, they reviewed the argument of the "housers," who are "convinced that better dwellings and neighborhoods are the most effective and direct means of improving the human condition" (p. 96). The problem with this approach is that it can quickly substitute the goals of the planners to the wishes of households and lead to improper standards and the imposition of consumption patterns which intended beneficiaries might not choose if given alternatives. Since households do not have a housing problem as much as an income problem, the only recourse is a better knowledge of the structure of housing demand. At the aggregate level, if one overestimates the total volume of resources which "should" be available to the housing sector, there is a good chance that a few "high quality" (i.e., "high standards") projects will be produced and that they will crowd * This article draws on a recent study of the Korea housing market conducted for the World Bank. However, the author is solely responsible for this article, which may not be quoted as representing the views of the World Bank or its affiliated organizations. Special thanks are due to Leland Burns and Leo Grebler, who kindly made thei r original data available for further analysis. A Leland S. Burns and Leo Grebler, "Resource Allocation to Ilousing Investment: A Comparative Analysis," Economnic Developmtient and Cuhltural Change 25, no. I October 1976): (hereafter referred to by page number in text), 1980 by The University of Chicago ,2-0022S

3 Economic Development antd Clultural Cliange out other more desirable forms of housing investment, the end result being mostly misallocation of resources within the sector Nsith no overall increase in the total volume of investment. The second type of argument relates to the "pr()loict iwty theory of housing," for which the autilors thenise-l es have found only limited empirical support or consistent evidence. A possible reason is that the theory is conmposed of two distinct elemetnts wvhich should probably not be mixed. One stran(d consists in saying that better housing \Nill imilpr'ove health and the productivity of labor, increate eduicational efforts, anld reduce crime, Those are not unreasoniable expectations; but such improvements could very well be achiee cd with limilited in%esimcnt In mdilldidu.t. housing and major efforts in neiglhhorhoodl improvemenits in roads, water stupply, drainage, and sewerage as well as other utilities anid public services, all of which will be accounted for under "other co nstructioni" or "social overhead" in national accounts, The other strand of the productivitv theorv of housinig is hardly distinguishable from the third type of argument that holusilng investment is closely related to general development. Burns and Grebler define "the optimum split between housing investnment as the point where the marginal contribution l Of! L-silig to ntationial Intcomne just equalis the dlecrease in the contribution of alternative sectors resulting from an adiditional in'.c:tnlent in housing" (p. 98). In other words, one wouldl expect the level of inlvestment in housing to be closely related to the opportunity cost ol capital in the country and the expectedi retuirni on1 h1r1using pri)jcts (which is the Keynesian concept of marginial eflicicncy of inmcstnlent applied to housing). The share of housing investment in total output will increase when the scarcity of capital bccomt1es less i1telcnse. In that respect, it must be kept in mind that n1onresiirndeti,il coinstruiction could yield highler returns to capital thani housing while pro\ iding just the same kinds of indirect employment andl income benefits so often mentioned as argumentts in favor of housing proorlams. Using a cross-section sample of 39 counitries uith a large representation of more developed economies, B-G report the following orders of magnitude for the ratio of investment in residential housing to GDP, which they call the shiare of housing in total output (SHTO): for $ percapita GDP (in U.S. doflars), StITO 2.75; lor S380 1,250, SHTO = 4.42; and for $1,300()3,000, SHITO These are fimire. from their sample for the period (B-G, table 1, p. 103) in 1970 dollar equivalenits. They could hardly be used directly for any country because of several sources of variations ini the level of SHITO around these tides andignit also because of the measuremtletnt errors iiileieini in the data base used. Graphically, the results for the 39 counltries y-iel(d a rather "mootlh curve (fig. 1). An obvious test of the nonlinear relationship established by B-(J is to analyze the behavior of SHTO in a single country over timne. In that 390

4 6-4 - /.1. 2 I I ji V ,000 FIG. I.-Diagram showing the relationship between SHTO and GDP per capita. The arrows reflect the change in the value of SHTO and GDP between the two sample periods and for a given country. Source.- Leland S. Burns and Leo Grebler, "Resources Allocation to liousing Investment: A Comparative Analysis," Economic Development and Cultural Cnange 25, no. 1 (October 1976i I1

5 Economic Development and Ctultural Change case, there is no particular problem in the measurement of either GDP or GNP because they can be calculated in internally consistent conlstant domestic prices. It is well known that internationl I conmparisons base(d on GNP converted into dollars at official exc.langc rates are biased. The research by Kravis et al. has shown that levels or output in dollar terms overstate the gap between low- andi highi-inicoime countries.2 Hlowever, correctionis for such distortions were niot possible for the B-G crosscountry sample. An anialysis based otn Korea would be instructive in cross-checkinig the original findings because it is a countr) whiclh has experienced a very high rate of growtth over the last 15 years. It is also a country where housing problems are quite serious, offerin- a good test for the stability of the nonliniear relation between lhousing in iectinent and per capita output. Burnis anid Grebler rely on economic antid demographic v ariables to explain SHTO. In a first test, we can coin pare the Korean results xkith the B-G cross-sectional sample, relying e\c lusive!y on per capita GNP as an explanatory variable. Table 1 sumiarize, the performance of the Korean housing sector over the period , aleraged by 5-year periods corresponding. to the successive economnic plats. Also includeed are the otlicial projections of the cturrenit fouitli 5-year plan and the sample nmealns reportedi by B-G for the perio d 1,)('7 70 in their paper. It ca;n he seenl that ini Korea the behlaxior of SFIHT() conflorms very well to the nonliniear relationship identified by B-(G. Becaulse the strongest findina of the B-Ci paiper is that of' a nonilinear relationship betweeni SHTO and per capita GD1", ue have comnp.ired four common nonlinear models for both Korea and their sample (data. An additional reason for ig1no1ring demographic N ari'l'l+1e in this lirst series or tests is their lack of signiticance in the scod-perli oll (1967 7() 2 The World Banik and the U.N. Statistial Offi c hdse b'en %pon,oi in a project oii international comnparison undier the direction of Irs ing Krrlis Bsev Iriting KraNis, Zoltan KenesseY, Alan Ileston, and Robert Suinmers, A4 Si uen of International (7oinparison ofg;;-os.% Prodtuct atnd Ptrclhsi;g Porer [B3altirnore and London: Jolins Il1(rkins University Press, 1975] and Inicrzationral of'npai.ions R a ar J:'r;twt and 1Pw;c.ra,ini' Pftv- 1Baltimnorcand London: Johns Hopkins I 7m rsity Prses. I )781). Care must be esercised when using the B-G, equuation.'ith dollar salues. All Korean GNI' values are in conistanlt 1970 \sons conmei-ted into 1'.S. dollars at the 19!70 exchange rate. The results are drainatically t1fllermil from current \sons at the Ct:Urent exwhange rate, as can he seen for selcte(r years oif Korea per capita GIN I: (ONP in ('uirent Dollars (inp It ( oin'tant Plrices itn lt'7u D)ollars) t9' W7 1971,., ) It must he kept in mind thlat the 1.XS. dollar is not a constant aids%tick arid has lost 48.' ( of its domiestic %aluc hetmeen 1970 (presumedt (late for the 13-( sanmple) and V. 392

6 TABLE I SHARE OF HOUSING IN TOTAL OUTPUT: KOREA COMPARED WITH BURNS AND GREBLER SAMPLE Per Capita SHTO SHTO SHTO Population Urbaniza- GDP Projected Projectedt Projected Growth tion (in 1970 SHTO (Burns- (Korea, (Korea, Period Rate* Indicator* Dollars)* Actual* Grebler) eq. [5]) eq. [3]) Postwar transition ( ) First Plan ( ) Second Plan ( ) Third Plan ( )... 1, Fourth Plan ( ) t 2.20t 865t Sample means for group of 39 countries SOURCES.-PrGjections for the Fourth Plan were obtained from Republic of Korea, Bureau of Statistics, Economic Planning Board, Trze Fourth Five- Year Economnic Development Plan, (Seoul, 1976). Other data on Korea were obtained from Republic of Korea, Bureau of Statistics, Economic Planning Board, Korea Statistical Yearbook, various years. Data for the Burns and Grebler 39-country sample were obtained from Leland Burns (personal communication, February 1978). NOTE.-SHTiO = share of housing in total outpui. p5-yr average. tplan projections.

7 Econonic idevelopment and Ctultutral Change equation reported by B-G; their significance in the pooled data analysis reported by B-G is entirely due to the first-period sample. Four equation forms are used: (a) a quadratic form to conform with the B-G findings; (h) a reciprocal transformation implying an upper limit to the value of SHTO; (c) a logarithm-inverse transformationi implying an upper limit for SHTO and also an inflection point and a curve pas,sing through the origin; al d, finally, (e1) a double-log regression. The results presented in table 2 confirm the B-G choice of a quadratic equationi (e.g., eq. [2]) for the 39-country sample. For Korea the results are statistically quite good for all models, but the quadratic form (eq. [1]) is not acceptable because it yields results inconsistent with the actual behavior of SHTO: The value of SHTO would peak at the unrealistically low income level of $375 because ot' the restricted range of income values. On the other hand, the two nonlinear equations embodying a limiting value for SHTO are quite satisfactory. The reciprocal transformationi (eqq. [3] and [4]) yields limiting values for SHTO that are almost identical for Korea and the 39-country sample at 5.4. The logarithm-inverse transformationi (eqq. [5] andi [6]) yields results that are also consistent wvith actual patterns observed for Korea and the cross-section sample. In particular, the limiting value for Korea of 7.58 is within the range of the highest levels of housing investment reported by B-G. In the B-G cross-sectional sample, the better fit of the quadratic equation can be attributed to the single U.S. observation where GDP per capita is much larger than for the rest of the sample and SHTO is low and equal to 4'. Using the fitted equations for Korea yields the interesting result that by any of three standards the Korean Fourth Plan has selected a target value of SHTO of 3.60 which is low. It is two standard errors or 36'>( below the predicted value of 4.90 derived from equation (3) (table 2). There is the possibility of serious imbalances in the housing market if Korean planners who can affect the level of investment in housing adhere to this target level of SHTO. The equations estimated until now yield very useful insights into the dynamics of residential construction in Korea. It remains to be seen whether the demographic variables used by B-G could improve the model further. The results of afernatike formulationis of the nonlilnear relationship suggested by B-G are presented in table 3. It is quite clear that the omission of demographic variables from the mnodel involves no loss of statistical significance: When per capita GNP is omitted, the national rate of population growth is the most significant variable (see eqq. [2] and [3], table 3); when per capita G3NP is included, all demographic variables become insignificant. Alternatively, one may ask whether econiomic variables more closely associated with the concept of the marginal efficiency of investment in housing could yield improved statistical results. In additioii to the per capita GNP variable which influences the demand for housing, we con- 394

8 TABLE 2 ALTERNATIVE MODELS OF THE NONLINEAR RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN SHTO AND GNP PER CAPITA Limiting Functional Form a b c Value SHTO R2 SEE F-Value Y=a +bx+cx 2 : Eq. (1). Korea Maximum (.022) (.0001) y= 3.85 x= $375 Eq. (2). 39 countries yv=5. 8 7, (.83) (.326) x= $1,57 0 Y= a- Nx: Eq. (3j. Korea a= (17.36) Eq. (4). 39 countries a= (.08) In Y=a-bx: Eq. (5). Korea c (6A47) (I. 162)* Eq. (6). 39 countries e'= (.018) (1.337)* In Y=a+b In x: Eq. (7). Korea None (.106) (I.188)* Eq. (8). 39 countries None C (.052) (1.372)* NOTE.-SHTO = share of housing in total output; SEE = standard error of estimate. *When 1n Y is used, the reported value of SEE must be converted to antilog values for comparisons with the other equations. CD

9 TABL.E 3 EFFECT OF DEMOGRAPHIC VARIABLES Intercept URB URB2 DPOP DPOP2 I'GNP R2 SEE F-Value k Eq. (1). SHTO ** -1.06** (3.28) (2.49) (.45) Eq. (2). SHTO ** 2.81** (5.56) (4.79) (.99) Eq. (3). SHTO ** ** (9.87) (6.90) (1.08) (3.34) (1.46) 3 Eq. (4). SHTO *** (8.71) (4.62) (3.44) (6.83) (1.27) (7.80) NoTE.-URB annual rate of growth of cities over 100,000 divided rate by of increase the average of national rate of growth population; in national SEE population; standard error DPOP of estimate; annual SHTO = in parentheses. share of housing in total output; standard errors are given **Significant at 95%c level. ***Significant at 99%7c level.

10 Bertrand Renaud sidered two variables reflecting the supply of capital: the ratio of domestic savings to GNP (DOMSAV) and the rate of interest observed on the unregulated money markets (UMM), also referred to as the noninstitutional money markets. This rate of interest could be considered an acceptable proxy for the actual cost and scarcity of capital in a given period and is monitored by the Bank of Korea. In recent years it has fluctuated around 3.4% per month for the third quarter of the year when inflation has been about 10%XG-I 5%/ yearly. In the absence of a significant mortgage market for housing in Korea, the interest rate on the curb market gives an indication of the financial constraints placed on housing investment during a given construction season. It can be seen from equation (3) in table 4 that both supply variables DOMSAV and UMM can be found significantly related to the level of housing investment with the right signs. However, when they are introduced jointly with per capita GNP as in equation (6), they are found insignificant. In addition, their signs are unstable and are often contrary to expectations, a situation which may be caused by the high correlation between GNP and DOMSAV of.917. It is very likely that a more sophisticated model of housing finance wvould be effective in explaining the behavior of SHTO. However, since we are presently interested in a simple and robust procedure, we cani conclude that the earlier models estimated in table 2 based only on the value of per capita GNP fully meet our objective and provide useful information. Thus, the analysis presented for Korea supports the earlier findings of B-G. In particular, the existence of a nonlinear increase of SI ITO as the economy expands is supported. Whenever one is reviewing the housing sector of a country, it should prove useful to estimate a country-specific equation. However, two important considerations should be added to this discussion. They relate to the possible underreporting of housinig investment in low-income countries where squatters and illegal housing units are likely to be both significant and unreported in official statistics. In that case, the nonlinea- relationship between SHTO and GNP per capita may be an artifact. Another factor which may also influence the SHTO curve is the nature of the climate in the country studied. First, if the value of SHTO at very low levels of income is underestimated because of the important role played by squatter housing and because of the possible underreporting of housing construction, what could be the magnitude of the bias? An order of magnitude can be estimate(d for the year This was the peak year in terms of squatter appearances in Seoul, where about 66c'( of all illegal units were concentrated in Korea. During that year, about 18,500 net ne\k illegal units appeared in Seoul and 140,000 units were officially reported built around the country. 4 1 If we 4 The figures for the number of illegal units are derived from data compiled by the Seoul Special ciy Government. The share of illegal units found in Seoul is based on data reported in E. Mills and B. N. Song, "Korea's Urbanization and UJrban Problems," Korea Development Institute Working Paper no (Seoul, 1977), table A

11 w ti coo TABLE 4 EFFECT OF VARIABLES REFLECTING FINANCING CONDITIONS Observa- Intercept I GNP DOMSAV I DOMSAV UMM R SEE F-Value tions (N) Eq. (1). SHTO *** 6.53*** (1.43) (5.81) (4.62) Eq. (2). SHTO *** * (.28) (2.03) (.55) Eq. (3). SHTO ** -. 96*** (1.06) (1.02) (.25) Eq. (4). SHTO *** (1.41) (3.26) (.27) Eq. (5). SHTO *** (.64) (3.47) (.22) Eq. (6). SHTO *** (1.67) (8.84) (5.78) (.23) NoTE.-DOMSAV = ratio of domestic savings to GNP; UMNIM = unregulated money markets; SEE share of housing in total output. *Significant at 90% level. *"Significant at 95%oc level. ***Significant at 99%,c level. - ctandard error of estimates; SHTO=

12 Bertrand Renaud assume that in Korea the value of a squatter unit is one-third that of a legal unit, the omission of squatter units would bias the SHTO curve downward for Korea in 1968 by about 6.7cw (i.e., SHTO in 1968 could have been 3.35% instead of 3.219().5 This is not a very Pirge difference compared with the standard error of the estimate in the regressions presented earlicr, A more important factor is the possible role of climate in affecting the SHTO curve. Most of the countries in the B-G sample are in the temperate zone and have an important cold season. A comparison of SHTO for Korea and Taiwan, which are two countries with very similar economic growth patterns and relatively comparable cultures, suggests that climate may have an important impact on the value of SHTO. At comparable levels of per capita GNP, the value of SHTO is systematically lower for Taiwan than for Korea (SHTO is 2%t instead of 3%) 3 Because of the rigorous climate, the scarcity of land, and the cost of construction materials (granite or cement rather than clay), the relative cost of housing is significantly higher in Korea. Because of the very different relative prices between housing and nonhousing goods, the values of SHTO differ markedly between the two countries anid follow different paths. If the climatic difterential suggested by the comnparison of Korea an(i Taiwan is generalizable--and it should be--the implicationis of the B-G anal)sk are very clear: The volume of rehidential conistructioni actikities will be the smnallest in tropical countries at the lowtest level of per capita GNP. On the other hand, the significance of the housing sector w ill be the greatest in temperate or cold countries at medium- to high-inicome levels. Because recent analyses show that the income elasticity of demand for housing is less than one in less developed countries (LDCs) as well as in developed countries,t there appear to be important limitaitions to relying on housing as a stimulant to lo%k-income tropical LLDC economics, as often advanced by those whom B-G have called "housers." Other avenues for raising welfare and income levels may be more proniising, such as provision of other types of urban services which generate greater externalities as well as employment opportunities in the construction industry. lr4orld Bank BERTRA,N) RENAUD 5The assumption that a squatter unit is worth one-third tihe value of a legal unit is based on unpublished survey data collected by the Institute for Utrban Studies of Yonsei UmNiser.siiv of Seoul in 1970 on construction costs and market values. If anything, it is overstating the relative value of illegal!,uu,ing in compairison with legal units. 6 See J. TFollain, C. C. Lim, and B. Renaud, "1The Demand for liousing in Korea," Journal of Urban Econooies (in press). 399

13 JOURNAL OF URBAN ECONOMICS 7, (1980) The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea' JAhlES FOLLAIN The Urban Institute GILL-CHIN LIM Northwestern University AND BERTRAND RENAUD The World Bank Received April 21, 1978; revised September 20, 1978 This paper presents the results of an analysis of urban housing demand for Korea taking into account the most recent findings of housing demand analysis concerning specification and aggregation biases. In order to obtain correctly specified demand functions, a procedure based on a model of the housing market originally proposed by Muth is used. Drawing on the detailed land information available in Korea, this procedure permits the calculation of an individual price per unit of housing services for each household. The results show conclusively that both the income and price elasticity of the demand for housing services in Korea are comparable to those found in the United States: the income elasticity is smaller than one and the price elasticity is negative and smaller than one in absolute value. Given the number of countries found within the per capita income range between Korea ($700) and the United States ($7800), the finding that these two countries have comparable demand elasticities is of major significance: in the absence of good national estimates, the order of magnitudes found here would be used for other country analyses. I. INTRODUCTION The need for accurate estimates of the response of housing expenditures to changes in income and prices is even greater in developing countries 'The research reported in this paper is based on a larger study of the Korean housing market organized by the World Bank under the overall responsibility of Bertrand Renaud. However, responsibilities have varied for each section of the analysis and the names of the authors are listed accordingly in the resulting papers. Primary credit is due to James Follain and Gill-Chin Lim in this paper. Helpful comments were received from several staff members of the World Bank and the Urban Institute, in particular, Gregory Ingram and Larry Ozanne. The authors are also grateful for the comments received from Tong-Hun Lee. The project has also benefited from Raymond Struyk's contributions to the design and the initial analyses of the survey. This study may not be quoted as representing the views of the World Bank and its affiliated organizations or the views of the Urban Institute /80/ $02.00/0 Copyright a: 1980 by Acadermic Press, Inc. All rights of reproduction in any form rcserved.

14 316 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD than in richer countries because housing problems are more severe and resources very scarce. Reliable elasticity estimates are needed for better forecasts of housing demand and the sound formulation of urban policies. They are central to the analysis of the incidence of property taxes on which so many local governments are or could be relying extensively. Further, in land-scarce countries such as Korea, it is important to develop better perspectives on patterns of city expansion or on the magnitude of suburbanization under the compounded impact of high rates of income and population growth. The results presented here are of interest for two additional reasons. First, the analysis takes into account the most recent findings on demand analysis which have shown that some of the previous uncertainty on the value of the income elasticity of the demand for housing services can be explained by a series of specification and aggregation problems (see Polinsky [17], Campbell and Smith [1, 23], and Lee and Kong [8]).2 In order to obtain correctly specified demand functions this paper uses a procedure based on a model of the housing market originally proposed by Muth. Drawing on the extremely detailed land information available in Korea, this procedure permits the calculation of an individual price per unit of housing services for each household. Alternative specifications of the demand equations allow the testing of the directions of the biases created by aggregation and specifications errors as recently discussed in the U.S. literature. Second, and more importantly, this analysis provides for the first time a consistent basis for comparison of the characteristics of demand under sharply different economic conditions: the per capita GNP in the United States was $7867 and it was only $710 in Korea in 1976 when the survey data for this study were collected. The results fully confirm the findings presented in recent U.S. articles concerning the direction of various biases which can affect the estimates of the demand parameters. They also show conclusively that both the income and the price elasticity of the demand for housing services in Korea are comparable to those found in the United States: the income elasticity of demand for housing is smaller than one and the price elasticity is negative and smaller than one in absolute value. The presentation of the results is organized as follows: First, Section II briefly describes the data base used for the survey and the characteristics of the housing market in Korea. Section III reviews briefly the state of research on the estimation of housing demand in the United States, and describes the method chosen for the specification of housing demand. 2 1n order to avoid repetition of previous work the reader is referred to these four recent papers for a comprehensive review of the state of the art in the analysis of the demand for housing.

15 HOUSING IN KOREA 317 Section IV explains how the theoretical model has been implemented and describes in turn the specification of the price per unit of housing services, household income, transportation costs, the sociodemographic determinants of housing demand, and the alternative forms of the estimating equation. Section V presents the results of the analysis. Section VI draws the conclusions of the study. II. THE KOREAN CONTEXT Korean housing standards are still extremely low in spite of the very high rate of increase in income over the last 15 years when the average growth rate of GNP has been around 10%o per year. At the time of the 1975 census the ratio of urban households to housirng units was 1.278, indicating that in cities 27.8% of the households cannot afford to rent separate dwelling units and can only find rooms to rent. This situation is due to the very high rate of urban growth 3 as well as the destruction of a significant proportion of the housing stock during the Korean War. Between 1955 and 1975 the population living in cities over 50,000 grew from 5.3 to 16.8 million. The analysis reported in this paper is based on the Farmily Income and Expenditure Survey regularly conducted by the Bureau of Statistics of the Economic Planning Board of the Korean government, which has been combined with a Special Housing Survey conducted in July The sample size is 1293 households with a reported monthly average income of 75,500 ($156) and ar. average of 4.9 household members. Forty-eight percent of these households own their dwellings. The sample average size of a dwelling is pyeong (613.5 square feet). These orders of magnitude were found consistent with the results of the Korean housing censuses. The sample survey shows that the median Korean household devotes about 15% of its income before tax to housing exclusive of such items as utilities, water charges, and home furnishings. The rent-to-income ratio by income group declines as income increases, as shown in Table 1. This decline if very marked and suggests that rental expenditures are not very responsive to income changes. For example, the ratio of the percentage change in rent between the 30,000- to 39,000-won income class and the 80,000- to 90,000-won class is only Yet it is impossible to conclude that demand is very inelastic with respect to income in the absence of 30ver the period South Korea experienced the highest rate of urbanization in the world for countries with more than 15 million people in See Renaud [19]. 4 Fhe original questionnaire design was prepared by Raymond Struyk at the time of a review of the Korean housing policy for the fourth 5-year plan, A full description of the regular housing and expenditures surveys based on monthly diaries and of the special housing survey can be found in Renaud et al. [20].

16 318 FOLLATN, LIM, AND RENAUD TABLE I Rent and Rent/Income Ratios by Income Class for Entire Sample' Income class (Won)b R/ Y R N Zero or not reported , ,000-39, ,000-49, ,000-59, ,000-69, ,000-79, ,000-99, , , , Average I (entire sample) Average II (excluding incomes less than 30,000) N= number of sample households in the income class; R = monthly rental expenditure (zero or inputed); Y = monthly current income. bthe 1976 foreign exchange rate was 484 Wons to one U.S. dollar. information on price elasticity and without controlling for other factors affecting the demand of a given household. 5 In most developed countries households can be classified into owneroccupants and renter-occupants with no further breakdown. In Korea, however, seven types of tenure exist: In addition to homeov'rnership, the rental arrangements are in order of frequency: chonsei, security deposit with monthly payment, declining chonisei, pure rental, free housing, and government housing. These various rental arrangements are distinguished from one another by their payment schemes, terms of contract, and sometimes eligibility criteria. 6 In the two cases of declining chonsei and rent with security deposit, a household payment agreement has been converted 51t would not be correct to conclude from such a simple calculation that the demand for housing is extremely inelastic because other factors influencing the demand of a given household are not being controlled. For instance, the rent-to-income ratio could decline as it does in Table I even if the true income elasticity were greater than one in a case where the price elasticity is less than one and prices vary in such a way that high-income households face a lower price per Ullit of housing services than low-income households. 6 A full analysis of the determinants of home ownership and reliance on chonsei arrangements is presented in a separate paper by Lrim et al. [9]. Honie ownership in Korea is not widespread (48.3% in our sample) because of the limited availability and terms of mortgage money and absence of tax benefits. Borrowing from the extremely active unregulated money

17 HOUSING IN KOREA 319 TABLE 2 Rent and Rent/Income Ratios by Tenure for Entire Sample Tenure R/Y R N Owner , Free housing , Government housing ,222 9 Chonsei (0.130)a 8,164 (290) Security deposit , Declining Chonsei , Rent , athe rent/income ratio for Chonsei is seriously distorted by the figure for the income group 1-29, 999, where the value of the ratio is 5.24! Elimination of observations relating to that group only yields a mean ratio for the rest of the population of into an imputed monthly rental charge. 7 In the other five cases no additional computation was required since households were asked to convert their rental arrangements into an imputed monthly rental charge. It may seem strange that owners would know precisely such a number. In Korea, however, it is quite believable because owners frequently sublet part of their homes so that ti ey are quite aware of the rental values of their homes. The estimates of imputed rent by occupants of government housing and free housing are more suspect. Therefore, we report results obtained with and without this relatively small part of the sample. Table 2 lists the seven tenure arrangements encountered in the sample as well as the average rent and the average rent to income ratio for each tenure arrangement. These imputed rental charges-either calculated or reported-are used as the measure of housing expenditures in the housing demand equations. markets is not possible because the rates are very high (between 3 and 5% numthly) and the terms of maturity very short (typically a maximum of 20 months). The chonsei is based on this capital scarcity: instead of a monthly rent the households give a deposit varying generally between 250,000 and 600,000 wons to the landowner, who places the funds on the money markets or uses them; the total deposit is returned in whole (in the case of a pure chonsei) or in part at the end of the lease. The pure rent, Western style, is used only by the poorest households. 7 For a declining chonsci the imputed rent is estimated as R z [(A -D - t)i + DIII,,-, where A = amount of original chonisei, Dr monthly deduction from chonsei, n = period, i = curb market interest rate. For security deposits with monthly rent, R is equal to the monthly rent to which is added the deposit multiplied by the monthly curb rate. The unregulated money market monthly rate for the sample households is estimated by taking the ratio of imputed rent to chonsei deposit in the sample chotisei data. The average value of i /month is very consistent with the regular monetary market surveys conducted by the Bank in Korea.

18 320 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD III. THE CHOICE OF METHOD The model of demand estimated in this paper is one of a general family of models of housing markets in which the central units of measurement are units of "housing services" and "housing stock." Given some minimum amount of operating inputs, each unit of housing stock produces one unit of housing services per period. Housing services refer to the sum of all services, inclusive of neighborhood attributes, provided by a housing unit during some period of time such as space, privacy, availability and dependability of utilities, and other features of the unit which provide comfort and pleasure. Given the price per unit of housing services (p), the rent of a dwelling unit measures the units of housing services (q) produced by a dwelling since rent equals p. q. Similarly the value of a dwelling unit equals the price per unit of housing stock (P) times the units of housing stock embodied in the dwelling unit (Q). The principal developers of this family of models are Mills [11] and Muth [14]. The most specific model which underlies the estimates reported is that developed by Muth [15, 16]. The details of the model are discussed below; here, an important reason for employing the model is noted. One of the most salient features of the model is that the price per unit of housing stock (and subsequently, housing services) can be constructed from the price per unit of land, the prices per unit of structure, and the shares of housing expenditures attributable to land and structure inputs. Since such data are available in Korea, a price term can be included in the demand for housing equations we estimate. As long as a unit of existing housing stock and an identical unit of new housing stock produce the same quantity of housing services, this measure serves as a measure of the price of both new and existing housing services. We feel this is a reasonable assumption which is commonly employed in studies of housing markets. Including the price term not only allows inferences to be made about the price elasticity of demand but also ensures that the estimates of the income elasticity are not biased because of the omission of a relevant variable (Polinsky [17], Strassheim [24]). An added advantage is that the procedure yields individual estimates of the price per unit of services for each individual household when past studies have frequently employed citywide indices. Polinsky [17] has shown that if demand is price inelastic, and prices decline with distance from the center of a city, then use of a citywide index rather than a more precise measure of the price faced by each household yields biased estimates of the income elasticity. The model employed has both a supply side and a demand side. The supply side is crucial to the construction of a price per unit of housintg services. The key relation on the supply side is the production function for housing services: q = q*(q, 0) = q*[q(l, N), 0], (1)

19 HOUSING IN KOREA 321 where q measures the units of housing services per period; Q measures the units of housing stock; L measures the units of land inputs; N measures the units of structure inputs; 0 measures the units of operating inputs. We assume operating inputs are proportional to the units of housing stock, so that q is directly related to L and N. This new production function, q = q(l, N), is assumed to be homogenous of degree 1. Profit maximization behavior by suppliers of housing in a competitive mark',t will satisfy the conditions PL/P ql, (2) PN/P = qn, (3) q = q(l, N) (4) where ql and qn are the marginal products of land and nonland, respectively. Muth [15] shows that the logarithmic differentials (e.g., q* d log q) of (2), (3) and (4) can be arranged as -knl* + knn* + op* = ap*} (5) kll* - kln* + ap* = ap, (6) q* kll*-knn* = O, (7) where a is the elasticity of substitution of land for structures in the production of housing. On the demand side, consumer responses to changes in p and y are derived from the standard utility maximiization problem. Max U(q, X) subject to pq + X = Y, (8) where U(q, X) is the household utility function and X is the quantity of all goods other than housing (the price of X is the numeraire and equals 1); Y is household income. Differentiating the first-order conditions for this problem yields the fourth and final condition for our system, q* = C'* + Eyy*, (9) where Ep and fy are elasticities of demand with respect to price and income, respectively.

20 322 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD Because the survey data provide rental expenditures we can solve (5), (6), (7), and (9) for (pq)*, which yields the two key results: (pq)* = (1 + Ep)(kLPL + knpn) + yy*' (10) p* = klpl* + knpn* (11) Equation (10) expresses changes in the demand for housing as a function of changes in the prices of land and nonland inputs and changes in income. Equation (I1) simply says that any percentage change in the price per unit of housing services resulting from changes in the price of land or nonland inputs is a weighted average of the percentage changes in PL and PN- The expression in the second set of parentheses in (10) equalsp* by (11) and suggests the following tvo-step procedure for estimating E p and ey First, calculate p* for each household using an equation based upon (11) from the survey data; second, substitute the calculated price p into Eq. (10) and estimate it using ordinary least squares (OLS). The problems associated with implementing this procedure are discussed in the next section. IV. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE MODEL Equations (10) and (11) raise five problems regarding the implementation and estimation of the demand for housing: 1. Choosing the appropriate approximation of (11) which pernmits the computation of the unobservable price per unit of housing services from PL, PN, kl, and kn. 2. Choosing the appropriate income concept and examining the sensitivity of the results to a variety of measures. 3. Adjusting for short-term variations in housing prices due to market disequilibria. 4. Adjusting income for transportation costs. 5. Identifying the principal sociodemographic determinants of the demand for housing. IV.1. Caleiulation of the Price per Unit of Iousing Services Equation (11) shows precisely how a given percentage change in the price per unit of land/or nonland inputs produces (in a static equilibrium sense) a percentage change in the price of housing. Unfortunately, Eq. (I I) does not allow the calculation of the price of housing services because it is expressed in terms of percentage changes (for which we do not have data) and not of actual prices (for which we do have data). The absolute level of p from PL' PN, kl, and kni can be approximated with an equation based on

21 HOUSING IN KOREA 323 Eq. (11). The obvious first choice which is eventually used is lnp = kl 1 npl + kn InPN. (12) This formulation is exact if the elasticity of substitution is unity, the value associated with the Cobb-Douglas pro,cwtion function. Although the Cobb-Douglas function is a frequently employed function, uncertainty concerning the value of a does exist. If anything, it is likely to be less than one (Muth [16]). If it is less than one, our estimates of a are probably upward biased. This bias results because our measure of p would understate the true change in p given some change in the price of land. This suggests caution in the estimates of a if they are large in absolute value. As seen below, the estimates are significantly below unity, so the bias does not alter our ultimate conclusion that demand is price inelastic. Although we do not have the exactpl orpn faced by each household, an excellent estimate is available because the Korean government keeps systematic records of land prices and publishes every year three land prices for each neighborhood or Dong. 8 The chosen measure of PL faced by a household is the average of the high. middle, and lowv prices of land per pyeong in the Dong in which the household resides. The housing construction cost per pyeong is derived from the construction cost records of the Korea National Housing Corporation. The data are based upon the nonland costs of constructing a particular type of apartment unit in eleven cities. 9 For the five cities in the sample not represented in these unpublished data, we assigned the cost figures provided for the nearest city. Because of the close geographic proximity of these cities this is probably not a serious error. The theoretical justification for this approach is that competitive forres eventually eliminate significant differences in construction costs between two nearby areas as long as transportation costs and localized market powers are not too great. This reasoning is confirmed in the analyses where estimates computed with and without these five cities are very similar. The factor shares, kl and kn, are calculated as kl=ipll/r; kn = l 1-kL, (13) 8 A Dong is an administrative subdivision of Korean cities. In Seoul, the number of households in one Dong varied between 1000 and 8000 households in 1975; a typical figure would be 3000 for Seoul. The official Korea Appraisal Board has been maintaining records of land prices by Dong since at least 1962 in most cities. This rather remarkable monitoring system is used in various ways in the implementation of land policies. See Doebele and Hwang [5] for an up-to-date review of Korean urban land policies, and Mills and Song [121 for an analysis of these data. 9 These cities are Seoul, Busan, Incheon, Chuncheon, Daejon, Jeonju, Daegu, Masan, Chungju, Weonju, and Suwon.

22 324 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD where i is the interest rate used to convert the land and nonland prices from prices per unit of stock to rentals per unit of stock per period. i is set equal to /month- Selection of this value is based upon two considerations. One, the rental values of the apartments built by the Korean Construction Company are between and of the total cost of construction per unit. This should be adjusted downward since the construction data do not include land costs. Two, kl typically equals about 0.33 for Korean homes. 10 From this value, the rental value of land can also be calculated since the definition of kl implies i = klr/lpl. Inserting the averages for PL, L, kl, and R of 63729, 12.9, 0.32, and 8251, respectively, into the equation yields a value for i slightly over This number may appear low in comparison to the 3.26% per month interest rate which can be earned in Korea's curb market. However, a rent-to-value ratio equal to does not mean landlords earn only 0.28% per month; it is perfectly consistent with the fact that a large part of Korean landlords' profits comes in the form of capital gains on the real estate which they own. Consider the following demonstration of this point. The rate of return can be expressed as Nl R + ra- X (14) where This is equal to NI = net income per month, V = value of assets, R = rent per month, ra = rate of appreciation of V per month, X = operating costs, property taxes and depreciation. NI R-X ra = i + CG, V + -V where CG is the rate of return attributable to capital gains. If i = 0.003, then the landlord needs capital gains of about 2% per month in order to earn a return competitive with that in the curb market. (One would probauly expect the return earned outside of the curb market to be less ' 0 ln a survey of recent housing units the share of land in total cost was found to vary between 40% for single-unit houses and 24% for apartments. See "Survey Report on Financing Status of Private Housing Funds," Korea Industrial Development Research Institute ' I.-,. 1976).

23 HOUSING IN KOREA 325 than the curb rate since the curb market is likely to be more risky.) It is not uncommon for land values to increase b) 2% per month; for instance, land values averaged about 3.2% increase per month in Suwon during the period 1968 to IV 2. Measurement of Income The choice of the appropriate measure of household income has been a source of considerable difficulty in practically all housing demand estimations. Many argue that for the estimation of the long-run income elasticity the appropriate measure is probably not the current rate of income which is easily measured, but rather the long-run expected income (the permanent income) which is not directly measurable. Choosing the appropriate variable is difficult but important because estimates of the income elasticity obtained using current period incomes are downward biased if the permanent income hypothesis is true (see Theil [25]). Given the nature of the survey data, two alternatives for measurement of the permanent income are used in addition to the monthly income reported in the survey. First, total household consumption expenditures can be substituted for the measure of household disposable current income. The reasoning is that the level of consumption is likely to be a good proxy for permanent income if, according to the permanent income theor). consumption is proportional to permanent income [6]. We use the log linear specification so the coefficient of consumption is the estimate of,e. An alternative which has often been proposed is to estimate the parameters of the deemand equation using groupedi household data as the unit of observation. e.g., SMSA. We choose to aggregate by Dong. This aggregation procedure is used under the assumption that the nonpermanent or transitory components of current income will cancel out when households are grouped bv factors unrelated to transitory income. This aggregation imparts an upward bias to the income elasticity estimates if rental expenditures are tightly grouped and the distribution of rental expenditures within Dongs is significantly tighter than their distribution throughout the sample. We have little information about the severity of this problem except that Dongs are thought to be significantly more heterogeneous than their counterparts (e.g., census tracts) in the United States. If the grouping produces estimates of the income elasticity significantly below unity, then knowledge of the upward bias will only strengthen the finding that demand is inelastic with respect to income. IV3. Adjustinent for Shiort-rutn Less De mi,and Variations in the current market price of howsing services are linked not only to variations in its long-run determinants but also to short-run fluctuations caused by excess demand. Since our goal is to estimate the

24 326 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD elasticity of demand with respect to the long-run price of housing, we introduce an additional variable into the demand equation which controls for short-run variations in the price of housing associated with excess demand. The variable (S) is a rneasure of the housing shortage in a particular city and equals the ratio of the number of households minus the number of housing units to the number of housing units in a particular city based on the 1975 census. We expect the sign of S to be positive, when statistically significant. In addition. if the price elasticity Ep is estimated with and without S, the estimates of p when S is included are expected to be algebraically smaller. The reason would be that failure to control for short-run variations causes variation in the long-run price of housing to be overstated, and consequently. estinmates of er, to be biased downlward. This procedure is analogous to efforts which include the vacancy rate as an explanatory variable in equations explaining the supply of housing (see de Leeuw and Fkanem [41). Estimates are computed with and without S. The differences in the estimates of f p and Ey with and without S are small but consistent with our interpretation. 1V4. Adjustment of Income for 7ransportationt Expenditures Muth, Mills, and others argue that the appropriate income concept in a demand equation for housing is income minus transportation costs whenever the marginial costs of transportation with respect to distance are positive- an eminently reasonable assumption (see Mutlh [13]). Precise measuremenits of the costs of transportationi expenses (e.g., gasoline, bus fare, etc.) and the opportunity costs of travel time are required. Since we were unable to find a sa1ti-sactorn Korean study of the value of travel time, we adopted the simplified but probablv reasonable assumption that transportation costs are proportional to travel time from the central city for which data were collected. IV.5. Sociodernographic Determinants of the Demand for Housing Some variables which were considered for inclusion in the demand equation included average age of household members, number and ages of children in the household, number of subfamilies in the household, sex and occupation of the household head, and number of people in the household. Household size was finally selected for inclusion in the complete demand equation because it performs most consistently. Since household size is often correlated with the other determinants considered, we suggest that household size be interpreted as a proxy for some of the sociodemographic variables which undoubtedly influence the demand for housing but whose effects are difficult to sort out precisely. Past research shows that the introduction of sociodemographic variables often leads to somewhat smaller income elasticities [8, 18].

25 HOUSING IN KOREA 327 V. THE EMPIRICAL RESULTS Essentially two types of equations are estimated. The first one uses tiie household as the unit of observation and includes either one of the two income measures. The equation is: In R = a 0 + a, In Y, + a 2 In P + a(3s + a4 1- HS + a. ln T where R = imputed or explicit monthly rental expenditures, Y, = current disposable monthly income, Y2 = total monthly consumption expenditu1res, S = the housing shortage variable (see above), HS the number of people in a household, T = travel time to central cit. (i = 1, 2), (15) The second type of equation uses averages of the vaiiables bv Dong as the unit of observation: lnr = a 0 o+ al ln Y, + a,inp +a 3 S +a 4 HS + a 5 T (16) where bars above the variables indicate that they have been averaged over all sample households in a particular l)ong. For example, one observation would be I~ Rij R/I Li where L is the number of households in the sample residing in the ith Dong, and Ri is the rental expenditure of the jth household in the ith Dong. The household income and expenditures survey on which the housing survey is based covered households located in 17 cities so that various groupings of observations could be made on the basis of city size as well as more common characteristics such as homeowners versus renters or highincome versus low-income households. A large number of equations were estimated but only the most important results are reported here. Two types of nationwide samples are reported as groups I and 2. Group 1 consists of all households in the original sample except (a) those in Jeju, an island off the Southern Coast; (b) those with reported zero income; and (c) those with a calculated land share kl not between zero and one." Only demand I 'The city of Jeju has been deleted because it is on an island 100 km off the Southern Coast of Korea for which transportation costs may be substantial in the case of building materials. Unfortunately, this is one of the cities for which local building costs data were unavailable. In the case of households with reported income of zero and/or calculated value of the land share outside the interval zero-one, deletion was necessary because of measurement errors.

26 328 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD equations based on individual observations are reported for group 1. The second type of sample, labeled group 2, is a sample slightly reduced in size by withdrawing from the group I sample the households presumed to be benefiting from government housing subsidies as well as households residing in cities without construction cost data. The basic results for the two national samples are reported in Tables 3, 4, and 5. In addition demand estimations based on group 2 were estimated on interesting subsamples such as owners versus renters, households residirg in Seoul (population, 7.5 million), households residing in Busan and Taegu (two other cities of over 1 million people), and households residing in cities other than the three largest. By estimating demand functions for such subsamples we can test for statistically significant differences in housing demand over groups which are of major significance to policy formulation. The results for these subsamples are presented in Tables 6, 7 and 8. Their discussion follows that of the analyses based on the two national samples (groups 1 and 2). V.]. Demand Results Based on the Nationwide Samples (Groups I and 2) The discussion of the national results is divided into five parts. The first four parts deal with the estimates of the elasticity of demand with respect to (a) income; (b) price, (c) household size, and (d) transportation expenditures. They are followed by an overall assessment of the demand equation findings. TABLE 3 Estimates of Demand la for Group lb. c Dependent variable Constant Y 1 Y 2 P S HS T R 2 ep R , Note. N = Standard errors are below the estimates. 'Demand equation I has the household as the unit of observation. bgroup I includes all observations in the sample except those with zerc. reported incomes, calculated kls not between zero and one, as well as households residing in Jeju. cy, = current disposable income; Y 2 = consumption expenditures; P = price per unit of housing services; S = housing shortage = ratio of number of households minus number of dwellings to number of dwellings; HS = household size; T = travel time to center of city; ep = price elasticity equal to regression estimate minus one.

27 HOT ISING IN KOREA 329 TABLE 4 Estimates of Demand la for Group 2 b, c Dependent variable Constant Y, Y2 P S HS T R 2 e ) X Note. N = 896. Standard errors are below the estimates. a'demand equation I has the household as the unit of observation. bgroup 2 includes all observation in group I minus those in cities without construction data and those residing in government housing. 'See footnote c, Table 3. for definitions of parameters. TABLE 5 Estimates of Demnand Fquation 1 1 for Group I ' Dependent vanable Constant Y, P S HS T R 2 cp (0.17) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.07) (0.37) (0.07) Note. Standard errors are below the estimates. ademand equation 11 uses averages by I)ong as the unit of observation. "Group I includes all observations in the sample except those vwith zero reported incomes, calculated k 1 values not between zero and one. and thlose residing in Jeju. 'See footnote c, Table 3, for definitions of parameters. (a) Income elasticitov estimates (E,). The estimates of the income elasticity equal the estimates of the coefficients of the income term since all variables are in logarithmic form. The estimates of fy obtained using national data are given in Tables 3, 4. and 5. Three major aspects of the results should be mphasized. First, the estimates of E y are less than one for the three measuis. of income used: the estimates of EY using household data and Y,, the reported income in the month of July 1976, range from 0.16 to 0.20 (lines 3 and 4 of Tables 3 and 4). The estimates of se obtained using Y, (grouped disposable income) both equal Second, the estimates are all highly significant in the sense that the ratio of the estimate of its standard error is always greater than 8 with household data and about 3.4 with grouped data. Third, the estimates vary with the income measure

28 330 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD TABLE 6 Estimnates of Demand Equation Ia for Special Groups: Owners vs Rentersb Dependent variable Constant Y, Y2 P S HS T R2 e 1. Owners (a) (0.04) (0.1) (0.01) (0.08) (0.04) (b) (0.04) (0.08) (0.008) (0.07) (0.04) 2. Renters (a) (0.03) (0.09) (0.007) (0.06) (0.03) (b) , (0.04) (0.09) (0.007) (0.06) (0.03) Note. N = 415 (owners); N = 481 (renters). Standard errors are below the estimates. 'Demand equation I has the household as the unit of observation. bsee footnote c, Table 3, for definitions of parameters. R TABLE 7 Estimates of Demand Equation Ia for Special Groups: Low vs High Incomeb, Dependent variable Constant Y 1 Y 2 P S HS T R 2 1. Low income (a) ,03 (b) High income (a) (b) Note. N = 640 (low income); N = 415 (high income), Standard errors are below the estimates. 'Demand equation I has the household as the unit of observation. blow-income households are those below the mean. High-income households are those above the mean. 'See footnote c, Table 3, for definitions of parameters.

29 HOUSING IN KOREA 331 R Dependent TABLE 8 Estimates of Demand Equation ja for Special Groups: Seoul; Busan and Daegu; All Other Cities in the Samplesb variable Constant Y 1 Y 2 P S HS 7' RI 2 e 1. Seoul (a) (0.04) (0. I ) (0.06) (0.05) (b) (0.04) (0. 10) (0.06) (0.05) 2. Busan and Daegu (a) (0.04) (0.18) (0.02) (0.09) (0.05) (b) (0.05) (0.07) (0.02) (0.07) (0.05) 3. All cities except Seoul, Busani, and Daegu (a) (0.05) (0.12) (0.01) (0.09) (0.07) (b) (0.06) (0(.12) (0.01) (0.09) (0.07) Note. N = 455 (Seoul): N = 264 (Busan and Dact-:u); N = 216 (all other - 'Demand equation I has the household as the unit of observation. 6See footnote c, rable 3, for definitionis of parameters. s except above). used. The estimates of E y using Y 2 and Y 1, our two proxies for permanent income, are about three times larger than the estimates of Ey using Y,. The findings of this analysis of Korean housing demand are remarkably simi!,ar to those of several recent studies of the income elasticity of the demand for housing in the United States (Carliner [2], Roistacher [21], Mayo [10], Polinsky [17], Smith and Campbell [23], and Lee and Kong [8]. The behavior of the alternative income elasticity estimates obtained when the three different income variables are used is quite consistent with the theoretical expectation that estimates of E, using proxies for permanent income are larger than those using current income n fact the ratio of one to three found for Korea is much larger than the U.S. and U.K. findings, where "on the average, the permanent income elasticity estimates of these studies are 50%o higher than the current income elasticity estimates," as summed by Polinsky [17]. One likely reason for the wider gap is that the Korean current income figure which had to be used is the income figt-re for the month of July 1976 reported in the diaries collected in the regular income and expenditures survey. A monthly income averaged over a 12-month period would have been much better but could not be estimated. The low elasticity based on current income may be attributed to this problem.

30 332 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD (b) Estimates for the price elasticity (es). The estimates obtained indicate that the Korean housing demand for housing is price inelastic. For the nationwide samples (Tables 3, 4, and 5) the estimates range from to The two cases of positive elasticity estimates arise when grouped data are used, and in these two cases the standard errors are large enough to find the two estimates not significantly greater than zero. In his 1977 paper Polinsky [17, p. 5] also finds that the use of grouped prices will bias the price elasticity toward zero. It must also be noted that, in the rest of the equations estimated, the price elasticities have larger absolute values when the better proxy for permanent income is used. On the basis of the estimates obtained using nationwide samples of individual households, the price elasticity of the Korean housing demand is within the range to This is consistent with the sketchy evidence already presented on the value of ep for Korean households [12], and the fact that the estimates are in agreement with the most precise study to date of the value of Ep-the Experimental Housing Allowance Program [10]. (c) Estimates of household size elasticity (ehs). The coefficient of HS is the elasticity of rental expenditures with respect to household size. This number, EHS. is estimated to be 0.36 and 0.14 when the income measures are Y 1 and Y 2, respectively, and the household is the unit of observation. The estimates are at least three times the value of their standard error. When the average by Dong is the unit of measurement, EHS is not significantly different from zero. This is probably due to the fact that average household size does not vary much by Dong. The estimates of the coefficient of HS are consistent with the hypothesis that the demand for housing is relatively insensitive to the size of the houso.ihold. This suggests that the urban demand for housing will not be muct affected by future changes in average family size. (d) Elasticity wvith respect to transportation expenditures (ET). Estimates of the coefficient of T, the travel time to the center of the city, indicate that the elasticity of the demand for housing with respect to T is quite small: ET is less than The precision of the estimates is very difficult to assess. On the one hand, most of them have the correct sign. On the other hand one would expect their magnitude to be closer in absolute value to the coefficient of income. The fact that the estimates of e. are typically four or more times larger than the estimates of et suggests that the proxy for transportation expenditure is picking up only part of the households' transportation expenditures, that is, the out-of-pocket travel expenses which are directly a function of travel time. The other component of transportation expenditures, the opportunity cost of travel time, is a function of income, not 13 When reading the regression results one must keep in mind that the coefficient of the price variable p is equal to 1 + ep.

31 HOUSING IN KOREA 333 distance. So, if more precise estimates of et are to be had, Korean estimates of the value of travel time must be made first. (e) Assessment of the overall equation. The demand equations using the national groups are very good. This assertion is supported by three kinds of evidence. First, the signs of the estimated coefficients are as expected, and the estimates are almost always significant. Second, the explanatory power of the estimated equations is reasonable for equations estimated using a cross section of households as a data base. The values of R 2 for the full equation range from 0.25 to 0.48 with the household as the unit of observation. R 2 reaches a high of 0.56 when the average by Dong is the unit of observation and Y 2 is the income measure. Third, the explanatory power and overall pattern of results are fully consistent with and quite comparable to those obtained in other studies of the demand for housing which used household data. V.2. Analysis of Special Suibsamples Additional demand equations have been estimated for groups of households which may be of interest to policymakers. The comparison of the results across groups also sheds light on the assumption that the parameters are constant across groups as implicitly assumed in the national group estimates. (a) Owners vs renters. 'Fable 6 presents estimates of the household demand for owners and renters. The results indicate that the income elasticiti' is larger for ovners than fior renters: E,; is estimated to be 0.62 (0.21) for owners when Y 2 (Y 1 ) is the income measure while EY is estimated to be only 0.42 (0.12) for renters. The differences in the estimates are statistically significant, and are consistent with those reported by DeLeeuw for owners vs renters in the Ulnited States [4]. A comparison of the estimates of the other coefficients suggests that the behavior of the two groups is similar in some respects but not in others. The price elasticity estimates are quite similar for both groups. The renters are slightly more responsive to houschokl size, but less responsive to transportation expenditures. Finally, consider the estimates of E, for renters and owners with the national estimates of group 2. Comparable national estimates, of Ey are 0.17 and Both are about midwav between the estimates of Ey for owners and renters. What is more important to note is that the results obtained using these subgroups are quite conisistent with the contention that ey is less than unity. (b) Low vs high-income households (Table 7). National estimates of Ey and Ep are important for some government policy considerations, but at other times policy development is aimed at the lower-income households. By separating group 2 by income at the mean sample income more precise

32 334 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD estimates of fy and fp for low-income households may be obtained. The estimates indicate that low-income households are much less responsive to changes in current income than high-income households (Y,), but not significantly different in their rcsponse to changes in consumption expenditures, the proxy for permanent income (Y 2 ). Since the estimates of EY are biased downward when current income is used as an income measure, the estimate of 0.02 for Ey obtained with Y 1 is probably much too low. The alternative estimates of ey with consumption expenditures as the permanent income proxy are probably a better guide to the responses of low- and high-income households. The conclusion is that Korean low-income households behave essentially in the same way as the higher-income households. Price elasticity estimates are also quite similar. In fact, the estimates of ep with Y 2 as the income measure are identical (- 0.27). The similarity continues upon comparison of the estimates of EHS and et. On the whole then, the fact that the estimates for the two subgroups are tot significantly different from each other and are not much different from the national estimates suggests that little is lost by pooling households with different incomes. (c) Grouping by size of cities. Three subgroups of group 2 have also been analyzed separately. They are Seoul by itself, Busan and Daegu, and the other remaining cities in the sample. Seoul is the largest city in Korea, (over 7 million residents), Busan and Daegu are the next two largest (over 1 million), and the third group of cities range from about 100,000 to slightly over a million. Estimating separate demand equations for these three subgroups provides some insight into the potential significance of city size for the demand for housing. Statistically significant differences arise among the estimates presented in Table 8. The income elasticity estimates (with Y 2 as the income measure) is largest in Busan-Daegu (0.68) and smallest in the group of smaller cities (0.37). The differences do not conform, however, to a simple positive relationship with city size, nor do they reverse the earlier claim that demand is income inelastic. The most significant differences concern the estimates of EP. The estimates for Seoul (-0.12 and -0.17) are quite consistent with the national estimates. Estimates of Ep for Busan-Daegu and the smaller cities are, however, three to four times smaller (algebraically). VI. CONCLUSIONS Given the significant number of countries found within the income range between Korea's income at the time of the survey ($710 in 1976) and the U.S. figure ($7870) the finding that these two countries have strikingly comparable demand elasticities is of major importance. Lacking good local

33 HOUSING IN KOREA 335 estimates of the price and income elasticities of the demand for housing policy analyses in other countries, one should rely on income elasticity estimates smaller than one and on price elasticity estimates also smaller than unity in absolute value. The best point estimate is 0.6 given that the estimates obtained with the two proxies for permanent income are the most precise. While further refinements of the findings presented in this paper are desirable, these first results give reason for optimism in that available econometric models developed for the analysis of cities in the United States could perform well in Korea and other countries, REFERENCES 1. J. Campbell and B. Smith, The demand for housing: A new look at urban empirncism, Paper presented at the Western Economic Association Meeting (1976). 2. G. Carliner, Incorne elasticity of housing dematnd, Rer. Econ. Statist., 55, (1973). 3. F. DeLeeuw, The demand for housing: A review of cross-section evidence, Amer. Econ. Rev. (February 1971). 4. F. DeLeeuw and N. F. Ekanem, The supply of rental housing, Amer. Econ. Rev., 61, (1971). 5. W. Doebele and M. C. Hwang, Land policies in Korea: With special reference to land development, mimeo (1977). 6. M. Friedman, "A Theory of the Consunpotion Function." Princeton Ulniv. Press, Pnnceton N.J. (1957). 7. T. H. Lee, Housing and permanent income: 'Tests based on a three-year reinterview survey, Rev. Econ. Statist (November 1968). 8. T. H. Lee and C. M. Kong, Elasticities of housing demand, Southlern Econi. J., 44, (1977). 9. G. Lim, J. Follain, and B. Renaud, The determinants of home ownership and rental arrangements in Korea, manuscript. 10. S. Mayo, "Housing Allowance Demand Experiment, Housing Expenditures and Quality," Part 1, "Report on Housing Expenditures under a Percent of Rent Allowance," Chap. 4, Abt Assoc., Boston (Januar-y 1977). 11. E. S. Mills, An aggregative model of resource allocation in a metropolitan area, Amer. Econ. Rev., (May 1967). 12. E. S. Mills and B. N. Song, "Korea's Urbanization and Urban Problems ," K.D.I. Working Paper No. 7701, Korea Development lns':tute, Seoul (1977). 13. R. Muth, "Cities and Housing," Univ. of Chicago Press, Chicago (1969). 14. R. Muth, Demand for non-farm bousing, in "The Demand for Durable Goods" (A. Harberger, Ed.), pp , University of Chicago Press, Chicago (1960). 15. R. Muth, The derived demand for a productive factor and the industry supply curve, Oxford Econ. Pap. (July 1964). 16. R. Muth, Derived demand for urban residential land, Urban Studies, 8, (1971). 17. A. M. Polinsky, Deniand for housing: A study in specification and grouping, Econometrica, 45, (1977). 18. A. M. Polinsky and D. T. Ellwood, "An Empirical Reconciliation of Micro and Grouped Estimates of the Demand for Housing." Discussion Paper 567, Harvard Institute of Economic Research (August 1977). 19. B. Renaud, "Economic Fluctuations and Speed of Urbanization: A Case Study of Korea, ," World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 270 (November 1977). 20. B. Renaud, G. Lim, and J. Follain, "Housing in Korea," to appear. 21. A. Roistacher, Short-run housing responses to changes in income, Amer. Econ, Rev. Pap.

34 336 FOLLAIN, LIM, AND RENAUD Proc., (February 1977). 22. P. Rydell, Measuring the supply response to housing allowance, Rand Pap. Ser. (January 1976). 23. B. Smith and J. M. Campbell, Jr., Aggregation bias and the demand for housing, Paper presented at the Econometric Society (December 1976). 24. M. Strassheim, Estimation of the demand for urban housing services from household interview data, Rev. Econ. Statist., 55, 1-8 (1973). 25. H. Theil, "Principles of Econometrics" Wiley, New York (1971).

35 Urban Studies (1980) 17, ( 1980 Urban Studies /80/ S02.00 Determinants of Home-ownership in a Developing Economy: the Case of Korea Gill-Chin Lim, James Follain and Bertrand Renaud [Received May 1979] It is often suggested that increasing the rate of home- considerable controversy, since incorrect measureownership is one of the major goals of national hous- ments of income are likely to result in biases in ing policy. The rationale is that greater home- estimated coefficients. For this reason, more recent ownership would improve the general level of housing research has attempted to test the permanent income quality and facilitate savings and wealth accumula- hypothesis using several alternative specifications tion of households. However, despite a pheno- (Kain and Quigley, 1972; Carliner, 1974; Struyk, menal expansion of literature on housing market 1974). None the less, there have been few attempts behavior in recent years, studies on the determinants to evaluate the relative importance of current and of home-ownership have received relatively little permanent income in a systematic way. scholarly attention in both developed and develop- These studies have also suffered from a lack of an ing countries. On the one hand, in advanced explicit consideration of the impact of housing countries the amount of research on home-ownership market conditions on the rate of home-ownership. falls far behind that on demand for housing services, In an effort to evaluate the effect of market conditions and much work is needed to refine the existing on tenure decisions, Struyk (1976) has estimated a analytical framework. On the other hand, in de- model of an aggregate demand for owner-occupancy veloping countries studies on household tenure usinlg data from 39 cities. Alternatively, Carliner decisions are virtually non-existent. (1974) has used dummy variables categorising size Previous studies on home-ownership conducted in of communities in an attempt to explain the effect of the United States have usually focused on the estima- regional differences on home-ownership. None of tion of the effect of household socio-economic char- these studies, however, have measured the effect of acteristics such as income, race, age, sex, and marital the long-run housing price on individuals' tenure status of household head and household size on decisions in an explicit manner. tenure decisions (Lee, 1963; Maisel, 1966; Kain and Another aspect often omitted from home-owner- Quigley, 1972; Carliner, 1974; Struyk, 1974). Among ship studies is the discussion of the role of household these household socio-economic variables, income mobility. Despite the salient impnortance of nobility raises one of the most difficult problems in estima- in tenure decisions, only Kain and Quigley (1972), tion. Most of the earlier studies used current income among the studies menitioned above, have offered ani as a measurement for household income. However, analysis of the relationship between home purchase the specification of the income variable inivolves a and household mobility. Gill-Chin Lim is Assistanit Professor, tile Techntological Institute, Aorthwiiesiernl University; James Follaini is economist, the Federal Home Loan Banik of San Franicisco; and Bertrand Rentaud is *Ieacl, Urban Affairs Division, OECD. Author's Note: The research reported in this paper is based on a larger study of the Korean hotusing market organised by the World Bank under the overall responsibility of Bertrand Renaud. However, responsibilities have varied for each section of the analysis and the names of the authors are listed accordingly in the resulting paper. Primary credit is due to Gill-Chin Lim in this paper. Gill-Chin Lim is grateful to Linda Lawrence for her research assistance. This study may not be quoted as representing the views of the World Bank and its affiliated organisations. 13

36 14 GILL-CHIN LIM, JAMES FOLLAIN AND BERTRAND RENAUD The purpose of this paper is to present an em- ownership and its estimation procedures. The fourth pirical analysis of the determinants of home-owner- section reports on the results of the empirical ship in a developing economy by employing a analysis. The paper concludes with a summary of methodological framework which overcomes some the results and discusses the implications of the of the deficiencies of existing studies discussed above. analysis. A substantial improvement in empirical estimation is made possible by the detailed housing survey and Home-ownership and Alternative Forms of Rental land value information available for Korea. More specifically, the present analysis attempts to con- angem i Korea tribute to the study of household tenure choice in The analysis reported in this paper is based on the several ways. First of all, this is the first serious Family Income and Expenditure Survey regularly analysis of household tenure decision behavior in conducted by the Bureau of Statistics of Economic developing countries. The study provides a basis Planning Board of the Korean Government and a for making observations on major similarities and Special Housing Survey conducted in July differences in household tenure choice between The sample size is 1293 households with a reported developed and developing countries. It can also monthly average income of 75,500 Won (US $150) serve as an important and useful guideline for hous- and an average of 4.9 household members. ing policy-making in developing economies. Second, Perhaps Korea is the country with one of the most the study offers an analysis of the relative importance sophisticated systems of rental housing market in of current income and permanent income. Third, an terms of the availability of options open to renters. explicit consideration of the effect of market condi- In most countries households can be classified into tions on individual decision units is provided by ownier-occupants and renter-occupants and no further employing a long-run price of housing services for an breakdown is necessary. In the Korean Housing individual household and an indicator of housing Survey, however, six alternative forms of rental arshortage. Finally, the study includes a measure of rangements are identified. They are chonsei, security household mobility to analyse its relationship to deposit with monthly payment, declining chonsei, tenure choice. free housing, government housing, and monthlv rent. The organisation of this paper is as follows. In These different types of rental arrangements are disthe following section a brief description of home- tinguished from one another by their payment ownership and various types of rental arrangements sclhemes, terms of contracts, and sometimes eligibility in Korea is presented. The third section explains criteria. Selected features of owner households and the specification of a model of the demand for home- six types of renter households are reported in Table l. Table 1 Selected Features of owner hotuseholdls and six types of renter htouseholds Months in Sample Household o Male-headed Number current No. (/ Size Age of head household working dwelling Owner 624 (48.3) Chonsei 357 (27.6) Security deposit with monthly rent 114 (8.8) Declining chonsel 70 (5.3) Free housing 13 (1.0) Government housing (free) 9 (0.7) Monthly rent 96 (7.4) Unclassified 10 (0.8) Total 1293 (100) l The original questionaire design was prepared by Raymond Struyk at the time of a review of tlle Korean housing policy for the fourth five-year plan For details of the income and expenditure survey and the housing survey, see Renaud, Lini and Follain (forthcoming).

37 DETERMINANTS OF HOME-OWNERSHIP IN KOREA 15 Traditionally, home-ownership has been the most is automatically deducted from the deposit. Thereimportant form of tenure in Korea. However, the fore, the actual rent paid by a renter is the imputed ratio of urban homc-ownership has continued to monthly value of the initial deposit plus the monthly dwindle in recent years. In 1960, the rate of home- payment. ownership in urban areas was 62.0 per cent and in Declining chonsei, which constitutes 5.4 per cent of 1970 it dropped to 48.4 per cent (Economic Planning all households, is another variant of chonsei. This Board, 1960, 1970). In our survey about 48.3 per type of renter makes a one-time deposit from which cent of the households are home-owners. The rapid a certain amount of due is deducted every month. rate of urbanisation, an enormous number of Any fund remaining at the end of occupancy is refugees from the north, massive destruction of the returned to the renter. Therefore, the actual amount housing stock during the Korean war, and rising of monthly rent equals the monthly deduction plus costs of land and capital inputs are often considered the imputed monthly value of the balance of the to be responsible for decreasing urban home-owner- deposit. ship. In addition, it should be noted that two of the A very small fraction of rental housing (in our major institutional factors which have encouraged survey I per cent) is offered free. Usually, free prohome-ownership in the United States and other vision of housing is practised between close relatives developed countries do not exist in Korea. Presently, or friends. Sometimes private companies also offer few mortgages are available for households through free housing to their employees. In some other an official financial sector and the national govern- instances, a renter is required to offer some form of ment does not offer any tax concessions to home- service to the landlord in lieu of monetary payments. owners. The Korean government created the Both local and national governmenits in Korea Korean Housing Bank 10 years ago to finance hous- own a small nunmber of free or rental housing units ing construction, but the amnount of mortgage funds for government officials, In our survey only 9 out from the Bank is very meagre. Although it is possible of 1293 households are reported as free government for households to borrow from the so-called un- housing occupants. Each governmental unit managregulated money market, the interest rates are un- ing these houses has a set of eligibility criteria. favourably high and the term of maturity is limited to a very short period, usually ranging between 1 and 2 years. The standard form of housing market transaction is, therefore, the full payment of the The theoretical basis of the model of tenure choice price of a dwelling unit at the time of purchase. is essentially the same as that of the demand for Chonsei is by far the most important type of rental housing services. Therefore, a general model of arrangement in Korea. The survey shows that tenure choice takes the probability of home-ownerchonsei renters account for 27.6 per cent of all house- ship as a function of household income, size, comnholds and 54.2 per cent of renters. Under this position, stage of life cycle, and the price of houising arrangement, a renter makes a lump sum deposit of services. Since we hypothesise that the tenure chonsei (usually translated as 'key' money) at the decision is also affected by short-run conditions of beginning of occupancy which is fully refunded at the the housing market and the mobility of households, end of the contract period. With this fund the land- we add two more explanatory variables. Thus lord usually makes an investment of his choice. symbolically, Therefore, the imputed rent of chonsei is roughly PO-f Y 14C P S M equivalent to the interest on the initial deposit. ( ' ', M) Security deposit with monthly rent covers 8.8 per where PO is the probability of home-ownership, Y cent of all households in the survey. This type of is some measure of income, HC is household charrental arrangement is a mixture of chonsei and acteristics, P is a measurement of the price per unit monthly rent. At the beginning of occupancy a of housing services, S is an indicator of housing renter makes a certain amount of deposit which is shortage in a city, and M is a measure of mobility. refunded when he moves out. But a renter is also Obtaining a reliable measurement of permanent responsible for paying a monthly due. In case a income is crucial to the study, because one of our renter is unable to pay the monthly rent, the amount primary concerns is the evaluation of the relative US 17/1-B

38 16 GILL-CHIN LIM, JAMES FOLLAIN AND BERTRAND RENAUD strengths of current income and permanent income. The price per unit of housing services (P) is con- For current income we simply calculated disposable structed from a neoclassical framework which asincome by subtracting monthly tax payment from sumes profit maximising suppliers and utility maxireported monthly income. For permanent income, mising consumers. 3 The price variable is intended we initially developed two measurements. One to reflect long-run market conditions. is a predicted permanent income using a multiple Housing markets are affected not only by the regression model and the other is consumption as a long-run determinants but also by short-run condiproxy for the permanent income. In our preliminary tions such as excess demand. To control for the experimentation, the latter proved to be a much effect of short-run variations in housing markets, we better measurement than the former. While the include an indicator of housing shortage (S). The former showed a very low level of significance and, housing shortage variable is obtained by dividing the frequently, incorrect signs, the latter was consistently Table 2 significant and always showed expected signs. 2 Variables list In this study we report only the results of the estimation using disposable current income (Y 1 ) and Dependent variable consumption as permanent income (Y 2 ). PO: Home-ownership dummy = I if the household is Several variables are selected to describe house- an owner hold characteristics; household size (HS), age of the Independent variables head of a household (AGEH), male-headed house- Y,: Monthly current disposable income in logarithm hold dummy (MALE), the number of family members Y 2 : Monthly consumption in logarithm working (NWORK), the number of members under AGEH: Age of head in logarithm 6 years of age (N6), the number of members under 20 MALE: Sex of head dummy 1 if male years of age (N20), and an elderly subfamily dummy NWORK: Number of members working (SFAM). The (N20 reason we include two variables for N6: Number Number of of members members under under 6 20 years years of of age age the number of children is to estimate the effect of the SFAM: Subfamily dummy = 1 if there is elderly subfamily age of children on tenure decision in greater detail. P: Price per unit of housing services in logarithm Since we are interested in the cstimation of the 8 Housing MON: Length shortage in of occupancy percentage in the dwelling in logarithm relative importance of various household char- of months acteristics, the multicollinearity problem cannot be overlooked. In order to avoid this problem, the cor- number of households less the number of housing relation coefficient matrix and the changes in the units by the number of housing units in a city. estimated coefficients among alternative specifica- Finally, a household's length of occupancy in a tions having a different combination of variables dwelling (MON) reported in the survey is used as an were carefully examined. It was found that the indicator of mobility. household size and the Lumber of members under The list of variables and their definitions are pre- 20 are highly collinear, having a correlation co- sented in Table 2. efficient of approximately We also noted that Several multivariate statistical techniques are the regression estimates were highly sensitive to available for the analysis of a dichotomous dependchanges in the specification. The corrective pro- ent variable. We have opted for ordinary least cedure we adopted is the specification of two sets of squares (OLS) estimation, despite the recognised equations which separate the two variables. econometric problems of the procedure. 4 There are 2 We have obtained similar results for an analysis of demand for housing services which are reported in Follain, Lim and Renaud (forthcoming). 3 The price per unit of housing services is calculated by the following equation: InP = klinpl+kninpn where P is the priee per unit of housing services, kl is the share of the value of total output spent on land input, PL is the price per unit of land, kn is the share of the value of total output spent on non-land inputs, and PN is the price per unit of non-land inputs. For detailed mathematical procedures in deriving this equation, see Follain, Lim and Renaud (forthcoming). 4 Some of the well-known drawbacks are: (1) error terms are likely to involve heteroscedasticity; (2) estimated probabilities may lie outside 0-1 range; (3) t.e linearity assumption may misspecify the true relationship; (43 the linear additive assumption cannot explain the multidimensional interaction effects among independent variables.

39 DETERMINANTS OF HOME-OWNERSHIP IN KOREA 17 several reasons for this choice. First, as shown by Results of Empirical Analyses some Monte Carlo studies of linear additive func- The model described in the previous section is tions, the loss of efficiency in OLS is rather trivial estimated for five subgroups of the sample. The for large samples (i.e., greater than 100) compared household income and expenditure survey and the to generalised least squares (GLS) (Goldfeld and speciai housing survey cover households in 17 cities Quandt, 1972; Sith and Cicchetti, 1972). Second ' in Korea. The grouping of the sample allows us to the mean value of the dichotomous dependent vari- observe variations in estimates among cities of differable in our study falls between 0.3 and 0.5, thus, ent size. The first group consists of the entire sample substantially reducing the occurrence of the prediced ale gingousid o th ('-. inervl.thid, except Jeju, a city on an island off the southern dicthe lac ofnrvoussde o ntere choice. coast (Table 3). The second group is composed of ountrev i s tdoes on t theiue of I cities for which the Korean Housing Corporation developing provides construction cost information 6 (Table 4). ii~dre complicated and expensive tools such as GLS The third group is Seoul, the largest city of the and logit analysis.5 The advantages of the more nation (Table 5). The fourth group is Busan and sophisticated techniques can be best appreciated only Daeuwi are The fourthird is cities, after* soeesnilfauesoreeiinso Daegu which are the second and third largest cities, e srespectively (Table 6). Finally, the fifth group contenure choice in developi.g countries are out- sists of eight cities of smaller size with construction ined. cost information 7 (Table 7). Table 3 Home-ownership regression models for all cities but Jeju* (I) (I1) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) Constant Yi (0.02) (0.02) Y (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) HS (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) AGEH (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) MALE (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) NWORK (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) N (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) N (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) SFAM (0.05) (0.05) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) p (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) S (0.004) (0.004) MON (0.01) (0,01) R * Standard errors of estimates are in parentheses. 5 The main advantage of GLS is its ability to handle heteroscedasticity. The problem of linearity assumption remains. See Goldberger (1964). The logit analysis best qualifies for S-shaped true relationship. See Nerlove and Press (1973). For a comparison of (?LS with other tools, see Jack Goodman (1976). 6 These cities are Seoul, Busan, Incheon, Chuncheon, Daejeon, Jeonju, Daegu, Masan, ChuLngju, \\VconJU and Suweon. The construction cost information was used to calculate the price of non-land inputs. 7 These cities include all in the third group except Seoul, Busan and Daegu.

40 18 GILL-CHIN LIM, JAMES FOLLAIN AND BERTRAND RENAUD Table 4 Home-owners/hip regression models for eleven cities* (1 I) (11I) (IV) (V) (VI) Constant Yi (0.02) (0.02) Y (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) NS (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) AGEH (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) MALE (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) NWORK (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) N (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) N (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) SFAM (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) P (0.06) (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) S , J.001 (0.005) (0.005) MON R (0.01) (0.01) * Standard errors of estimates are in parentheses. Table 5 Home-ownership regression models for Seoul* (I) (11) (III) (IVt) (V) (VI) Constant Yi (0.04) (0.04) Y (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) HS (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) AGEH A (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) MALE (0.09) (0.08) (0.09) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) NWORK (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) N (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) N (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) SFAM (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) P (0.1 1) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) MON (0.02) (0.02) R * Standard errors of estimates are in parentheses.

41 DETERMINANTS OF HOME-OWNERSHIP IN KOREA 19 Table 6 Ilonie-owniership regression nmodels for Busan and Daegu pooled* (I) (11) (1lf) (IV) (V) (VI) Constant Y (0.3) (0.3) Y (0.05) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) HS (0.09) (0.10) (0.09) AGEH (0. I 1) (0.1 1) (0.11) (0.10) (0.1 1) (0. 10) MALE (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0.08) (0.09) (0.08) NWORK (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) N , (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) N (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) SFAM (0.08) (0.09) (0.08) (0.07) (0.08) (0.07) P (0.14) (0.14) (0.13) (0.12) (0.13) (0.12) S....., (0.01) (0.01) MON (0.02) (0.02) R * Standard errors of estimates are in parentheses. Table 7!-ome-ownership regression mnodels for eight cities of smaller size* (1) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) Constant Y, (0.06) (0.05) Y (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) HS (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) AGEH (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) (0.13) MALE (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.10) (0.11) (0.10) NWORK (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) N (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) N (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) SFAM (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) (0.10) P (0.13) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) S (0.01) (0.01) MON (0.03) (0.03) RZ * Standard errors of estimates are in parentheses.

42 20 GILL-CHIN LIM, JAMES FOLLAIN AND BERTRAND RENAUD The results are generally consistent throughout effect of Y 2 is roughly three times stronger than that five groups. Although we are careful in interpreting of Y 1. The result strongly suggests a significant and the result of standard errors because of possible systematic difference between the effects of the two heteroscedastic error terms and inconsistent estimates income measurements for Korean households. This of standard errors, it is noteworthy to observe that is contrasted to the findings of a study for the US most key variables are,tatistically significant. The (Struyk, 1974) which showed stronger effects of signs of the coefficients are found to be correct in permanent income only for the younger families. most cases and those variables with unexpected signs are usually accompanied by standard errors large eniouglh to accept the null hypothesis of zero co- Houselhold Characteristics efficient. R square values range between 0.19 and Of the seven household characteristic variables, the 0.49, the average being This is a very high size of household (HS) turns out to have the most level of explanatory power, because R. values of significant and influential effect on the probability of regressions using individual data rarely exceed A due to the discrepancy due o te dscreanc bewee between thel-agesof the ranges of the ho expectations 1me-ownership. and All the signs coefficients correspond to are a statistically riori actual and predicted values of a binary dependent significant at the 1 per cent level in most cases. The variable. Comparable studies conducted in the magnitude of the coefficient covers a range of 0.20 United States report R 2 s of much smaller magnitude. 8 magnith a me oficienthis a that on The results for Busan and Daegu pooled e r and s fr the to 0.54 with a mean of the average This doubling indicates the that household on group of eight cities of smaller size are less consistent things size, with being other equal, will increase the probability of than others. Some of the results for these two home-ownership by It is also obs.rved that groups contradict the results for other groups. We the variation in the size of the coefficient among note that the sample sizes for the two groups are much different groups of samples is relatively small. We smaller than others and primarily concentrate on the consider the stability of the coefficient as an evidence interpretation of the result for the first three groups. for universal importance of the household size variable in tenure decision in Korea. Income Three other variables which characterise households' size and composition are also found signifi- Both current income (Y 1 ) and consumption as a cant. Except for a few equations for Seoul the effect measure of permanent income (Y 2 ) prove to have of the number of members under 6 years of age (N6) positive and significant influence on the probability is significantly different from zero at least at the 5 per of owning a home. Except for two cases, Y 1 is cent level. All signs are negative and the coefficient statistically significant at least at the 5 per cent level lies betveen and with the average of for a two-tailed test. The statistical significance of In contrast to N6 the number of members Y 2 is even much higher than that of Y 1. In most under 20 (N20) shows positivre signs for all equations. equations Y 2 is significant at the 1 per cent level. It is statistically more significant than N6. All co- In ternms of magnitudes of the coefficients, Y 2 also efficients are significant at least at the 5 per cent shows stronger effect on the probability of home- level. The variable's effect on the probability of ownership. The coefficient of Y 1 ranges between homne-ownership ranges between 0.05 and The 0.03 and 0.12 with a mean value of Since the average value of the coefficient is income variables are in logarithmic forms, the co- The interpretation of the coefficients of N6 and efficient of 0.06 for Y, means that a 100 per cent N20 needs some caution because they are estimnated increase in current inconme will result in the increase by two differently specified models. The coof the probability of home-ownership by For efficient of for N6 mcans a household with a Y2 we obtained a range of 0.10 to 0.30 and a mean child under 6 years of age is 6 per cent less likelv to of This implies that if a household doubles its be a home-owner than a household with the same permnanent income, the probability of owning a home size and characteristics but vithout a child under 6 is increased by The result indicates that the years of age. The degree of the net effect of an 8 Struyk (1974) reports R2 of for his OLS estimation. Kain anu Quigley (1975) obtained for their OLS.

43 DETERMINANTS OF HOME-OWNERSHIP IN KOREA 21 additional child depends on the family size. For simply explain that the existence of a subfamily, example, if a household of three members gains a which is defined as the parents of the head of the child under 6 years of age, the net effect on the household, increases the probability of home-ownerprobability of home-ownership equals which ship because of increased demand for home-owneris the sum of the effects of HS (0.143) and N6 ship.. An alternative interpretation can be derived (-0.06). For a household of four members, it is from the wealth aspect of the existence of a subabout T'herefore, for a given size of a house- family. It has long been a social convention in hold the presence of children under 6 years con- Korea that the first son of a household lives with stitutes a disincentive for home-ownership, but the his parents in their house 1 l even after his marriage net effect of an additional member under 6 years is and inherits the house. The inheritance of the house positive. Since the coefficient of N20 is estimated is often made while they live together. If this is the in a model without HS, the value of 0.07 simply case SFAM is not a cause for the increased proreflects the effect of an additional member under 20 bability of home-ownership, but a predetermined years and a direct comparison of the coefficients of factor for a higher rate of ownership. It seems that N6 and N20 cannot uncover the relative strength of both are reasonable interpretations, but we hesitate the two variables. To compare the relative strength to make any conclusive renmarks because of the lack of N6 and N20, the net effect of N20 is computed of information on the wealth of the households. We using a model which includes both HS and N20.9 believe this subject can be better investigated by a For a household of four it is about The result future study with detailed information on wealth indicates that the effect of N20 is stronger than N6. status of households. A reference to a couple of particular aspects of Age of the head of household (AGEH) shows an household composition and real estate practice expected sign for 27 out of 30 equations. The coseems useful to understand the result. First. in most efficients with expected signs are mostly significant Korean households children stay with their parents at the 5 per cent level. Three cases with unexpected until they graduate from college or get married. signs are not statistically significant. The average Therefore, pressure to own a house increases with value of the coefficient for the entire sample is about the increase in the number of grown-up children For Seoul it is The size of the co- The number of children in their early childhood has efficient covers a rather wide range ( ). This a smaller effect on the probability of home-owner- may be due to multicollinearity. Although we found ship, because children under 6 years of age can no large correlation coefficient between AGEH and always share a room with their parents.10 Second, other variables, it is possible that AGEH is pairwise as already described, a full payment of the cost of a independent and yet a linear combination of two or house at the time of purchase is a standard real more of other variables. estate practice in Korea. The accumulation of the The studies done for the US generally show that a capital equal to the full value of a house takes a female-headed household is less likely to be a homenumber of years of thrift, preventing many couples owner all other things being equal. The evidence with chili ren from becoming home-owners. presented here suggests that it could well be a reverse The presence of a subfamily dummy (SFAM) in Korea. The dummy variable for male-headed shows positive and significant effects on home- household (MALE) shows a negative sign for 26 out ownership for all groups except the group of eight of 30 equations. Eleven cases with negative sign and cities of smaller size. For the first four groups the four cases with positive sign are statistically invariables are significant at the 5 per cent level in significant. The size of the coefficient is quite large. most cases. The magnitude of the coefficient is The sitnple average from all equations is Two about There are a couple of alternative ways alternative explanations can be offered. It may be of interpreting the result for SFAM. First, we may simply due to a bias in sampling or the result may 9 This model is not presented because of the problem involving multicollinearity. For the purpose of prediction, however, it is still useful. 10 For a more detailed analysis of determinants of residential crowding, see Follain, Lim and Renaud (1979). " Studies on household composition in Korea indicate that a large proportion of Korean households are composed of more than two generations. See Kwon, Lee, Chang and Yu (1975).

44 22 GILL-CHIN LIM, JAMES FOLLAIN AND BERTRAND RENAUD reflect a particu!ar wealth status of female-headed Unless there is some major reorientation in the households in Korea.1 2 policy regarding housing finance and construction. Number of members working (NWORK) shows the national goal of raising home-ownership is not minus sign for all cases with average magnitude of likely to be achieved Except in six equations it is significantly different from zero at the 5 per cent level. This Housing Shortage is not unexpected because in Korea households with housing shortage more than two working members are relatively less The housing shortage variable (S) shows the least wealthythan others. Multiple-worker households are consistent results among all variables. The cousually employed inl low wage jobs. efficients are split between the two opposite signs: the magnitude covers a wide range (from to 0.18) and the significance level fluctuates. There The Price per Unit of Housing Services is only one case which is statistically significant at the The price variable (P) shows very consistent results 5 per cent level and has a correct sign (Model VI of for most equations. Except for the Busan and the entire sample) but its magnitude is negligibly Daegu models which show unexpected signs and small (0.008). This result implies that the household little statistical significance, P proves to be a highly tenure decision is not sensitive to short-run market significant and important variable. On the average conditions. the coefficient of P is The construction of P is based on the concept of the long-run equilibrium Mobility price per unit of housing services. Therefore, the The length of occupancy measured in number of coefficient indicates that a 1 per cent increase in the months in log (MON) is extremely significant long-run price of housing will result in the decrease throughout all equations. The value of the coof the probability of home-ownership by The efficient is very stable ranging between 0.12 and 0.18 simple fact that no other studies have examined the The average is A simple explanation of the influenceofhousingpriceontheprobabilityofhome- statistical significance of MON is that the more ownership precludes us from making any comparison mobile a household is, the less likely it is to own a to evaluate the reliability and the significance of the home. However, this interpretation tells only a part estimate. None the less, based on the statistically of the story. Empirical studies on household moving consistent results obtained for this study and our behavior suggest that owners are less sensitive to earlier study on the demand for housing services changes in work place location than renters.1 3 One (Follain, Lim and Renaud, forthcoming), we con- of the reasons is that the cost incurred in moving is sider our estimates with respect to the price variable normally greater for owners. The absence of the as fairly reliable. control for the effects of the changes in employment One interesting observation is made by comparing location and the prior tenure status discourages us the coefficients of P (-0.14) and Y 2 (0.19). If both from making a more definitive interpretation. Never- Y 2 and P rise at the same rate with other things un- theiess, even vith the assumption of a reciprocal changed, a household's probability of home-owner- causal relationship between the mobility and tenure ship is not likely to increase substantially. The data status, the high level of significance and sizeable compiled by Mills and Song (1977) suggest that magnitude indicates an appreciable influence of urban housing price has been increasing roughly household mobility on the probability of hometwice as fast as urban per capita income since ownership. Our results together with these data demonstrate why urban home-ownership has been decreasing over the past years. It is also evident that the demand for Summary and Implications home-ownership will further decrease if the present This paper has presented an analysis of the detertrend of faster escalation in housing prices continues. minants of home-ownership in a developing economy 12 The absence of detailed information on the wealth status of female-headed households in Korea makes it difficult to interpret the result in definite terms. This, again, points to the need for an investigation of the role of wealth in tenure decision. 13 See, for example, Brown (1975).

45 DETERMINANTS OF HOME-OWNERSHIP IN KOREA 23 using household expenditure and housing survey larger than average. The policy of concentrating on data from Korea. Some of the observations made the construction of owner-occupied units of small in the foregoing analysis can be surnmarised as dimensions may weil be re-examined. follows. First, the study indicates that permanent income is much more important and influential than REFERENCES current income in tenure decisions. The estimated tincome ise BROWN, 1-H. J. (1975). Changes results in workplace show that and the residential effect of permanent inconie is location1. Journzalofthe A4mter-ica Institute of Plalners, Vol. about three times as strong as that of current income. 41: Second, household characteristics are also important CARLINER, G. (1974). Determinants dt o. of home A ownership. Land determinants Economics, of Vol. home-ownershp 50: decisons. Among ECONOMIC PLANNING BOARD (1960). Repo-t on Popuilationi and several household characteristics variables examined, Housing. Seoul, Korea. the family size is the most crucial determinant of ECONOMICPLANNINGBOARD(1970). Reporton Population and hoine-ownership. homeownrshp. As s t to the effct effect of f te the nmbe number of FOLLAIN, Houtsing. J., Seouil, Lim, G. Korea. and RENAUD, B. (1979). The Ecotionlics children, the analysis shows that the number of of Residential Crovding in Developing Economies: Thze Case children under 20 years of age has much stronger of Korea. A paper presenteud at the Second effect Conference on the on households' py effects of on hmajor the households' International probability Economic of home- Issues. Los versity Angeles: of Southern Uni- California. ownership than the number of children under 6 years FOLLAIN, J., LIM, G. and RENAUD, B. (fortheoming). The of age. The effect of the presence of an elderly sub- demand for housing in developing countries. y ao Journal sm of s, b family also Urban seems Econonmics. signiicant, but more preclse GOLDBERGER, A. (1964). Econtometric Tlheo!y. New York: observation would require a further investigation of Wi ley. the role of household wealth in tenure decisions. GOLD FELD, S. and QUANDT, R. (1972). NonlinearAMethods in Third, of the two variables describing market condi Econometrics. Amsterdam: l- North-Holland. GOODMAN, J., JR. (1976). Is Ordinary Least Sqtares Estilnations, only the long-run price of housing services tion with a Dichotomous Dependentt Vtariable Really that shows statistically meaningful results. It is found Bad? Working Paper Washington, D.C.: The that the effect thattheeffct of f hosin housing prceson prices hme-wneshi home-ownership KAIN, Urban J. and Institute. QUIGLEY, J. (1972). Housing market discriminais highly significant, but the effect of housing shortage tion, homeownership and savings behavior. American appears to be insignificant. This result may indicate Economic Review, Vol. 62: that a household's probabit. that a household's hs.kain, J. and QUIGLEY, probability of home-ownership J. (1975). is Housing jvfarket Discriminiation. anid Racial New York: National Bureau of Economic largely determined by the long-run conditions and Research. little affected by short-run fluctuations in housing KWON, T., LEE, H., CHANG, Y. and Yu, E. (1975). Tle Popillamarkets. Finally, an association between mobility Studies Center, Seoul Nathie PoUulatn and Development and tenure status is noted. However, we reserve a LEE, T. H. (1963). Demand for housing: a cross-section definitive interpretation of the result because of the analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 45: 190- lack of control lackof fr for wrkpace workplace ontol changes hanes and te the pior prior MAISEL, 196. S. (1966). Rates of ownership, mobility, and purtenure status. chase. Essays in Urban Lanid Economics, Los The result of the analysis points to the crucial im- Angeles: Real Estate Research Program, University of portance of the portnceof housingprice iouingpric he inforulainghotsin formulating housing MILLS, California. E. and SONG, B. (1977). Korea's Urbanization and policy regarding home-ownership. The offsetting Urbant Pr-oblems. Seoul: Korea Development Institute, effect of price (-0.14) is smaller than that of income NERLOVE, M. and PRESS, J. (1973). Univariate if te husig pice anzd ontnue Mfiulti- to variate Loglintear (0.19). antd Logistic However, Mfodels. if Santa the housing Monica: The price continues to Rand Corporation. escalate twice as fast, as income, the demand for RENAUD, B., LIM, G. and FOLLAIN, J. (forthicoming). Houising home-ownership will actually decline. The rate of in Korea. home-ownership will not be increased without RICHARD PRArr ASSOCIATES INC. the korean Ecotonmy. (1977). A report ouisinig Fliantce prepared in for U.S. Agency supply side programs which can effectively reduce for International Development. housing costs. It is also noted that the household SMITH, C. K. and cicchett, C. J. (1972). Regression size variable, among all variables examined, shows analysis with dichotomous presented dependent at the variables. Allied Social A paper Science Association Conventhe strongest effect on the probability of home- tion, Toronto, Canada. ownership. The strong association between house- STRUYK, R. (1974). The determinants of household home *,* * hold.- size.ownership. and home-ownership implies that housing Urban Situdies, Vol. oweshp 11: STRUYK, R. (1976). Ura tde,vo Urbant Hoineownershi4p. Lcxington: units demanded for owner-occupancy are likely to be Lexington Books.

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values

Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values Hedonic Pricing Model Open Space and Residential Property Values Open Space vs. Urban Sprawl Zhe Zhao As the American urban population decentralizes, economic growth has resulted in loss of open space.

More information

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas?

What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas? What Factors Determine the Volume of Home Sales in Texas? Ali Anari Research Economist and Mark G. Dotzour Chief Economist Texas A&M University June 2000 2000, Real Estate Center. All rights reserved.

More information

DEMAND FR HOUSING IN PROVINCE OF SINDH (PAKISTAN)

DEMAND FR HOUSING IN PROVINCE OF SINDH (PAKISTAN) 19 Pakistan Economic and Social Review Volume XL, No. 1 (Summer 2002), pp. 19-34 DEMAND FR HOUSING IN PROVINCE OF SINDH (PAKISTAN) NUZHAT AHMAD, SHAFI AHMAD and SHAUKAT ALI* Abstract. The paper is an analysis

More information

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010.

[03.01] User Cost Method. International Comparison Program. Global Office. 2 nd Regional Coordinators Meeting. April 14-16, 2010. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized International Comparison Program [03.01] User Cost Method Global Office 2 nd Regional

More information

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan

Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan Review of the Prices of Rents and Owner-occupied Houses in Japan Makoto Shimizu mshimizu@stat.go.jp Director, Price Statistics Office Statistical Survey Department Statistics Bureau, Japan Abstract The

More information

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers?

How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? Dr Jens Mehrhoff*, Head of Section Business Cycle, Price and Property Market Statistics * Jens This Mehrhoff, presentation Deutsche

More information

Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States

Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States Housing Supply Restrictions Across the United States Relaxed building regulations can help labor flow and local economic growth. RAVEN E. SAKS LABOR MOBILITY IS the dominant mechanism through which local

More information

An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria through the Lens of Fundamentals

An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria through the Lens of Fundamentals An Assessment of Recent Increases of House Prices in Austria 1 Introduction Martin Schneider Oesterreichische Nationalbank The housing sector is one of the most important sectors of an economy. Since residential

More information

An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1

An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1 An Assessment of Current House Price Developments in Germany 1 Florian Kajuth 2 Thomas A. Knetsch² Nicolas Pinkwart² Deutsche Bundesbank 1 Introduction House prices in Germany did not experience a noticeable

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal

Volume 35, Issue 1. Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal Volume 35, Issue 1 Hedonic prices, capitalization rate and real estate appraisal Gaetano Lisi epartment of Economics and Law, University of assino and Southern Lazio Abstract Studies on real estate economics

More information

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners

Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners Joint Center for Housing Studies Harvard University Estimating National Levels of Home Improvement and Repair Spending by Rental Property Owners Abbe Will October 2010 N10-2 2010 by Abbe Will. All rights

More information

Initial sales ratio to determine the current overall level of value. Number of sales vacant and improved, by neighborhood.

Initial sales ratio to determine the current overall level of value. Number of sales vacant and improved, by neighborhood. Introduction The International Association of Assessing Officers (IAAO) defines the market approach: In its broadest use, it might denote any valuation procedure intended to produce an estimate of market

More information

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION

Chapter 35. The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION Chapter 35 The Appraiser's Sales Comparison Approach INTRODUCTION The most commonly used appraisal technique is the sales comparison approach. The fundamental concept underlying this approach is that market

More information

Examples of Quantitative Support Methods from Real World Appraisals

Examples of Quantitative Support Methods from Real World Appraisals Examples of Quantitative Support Methods from Real World Appraisals Jeffrey A. Johnson, MAI Integra Realty Resources Minneapolis / St. Paul Tony Lesicka, MAI Central Bank 1 Overview of Presentation EXAMPLES

More information

Resource Allocation to Housing Investment: Comments and Further Results. The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea

Resource Allocation to Housing Investment: Comments and Further Results. The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: The Case of Korea Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized World Bank Reprint Series: Number 183 Bertrand Renaud Resource Allocation to Housing

More information

Housing market and finance

Housing market and finance Housing market and finance Q: What is a market? A: Let s play a game Motivation THE APPLE MARKET The class is divided at random into two groups: buyers and sellers Rules: Buyers: Each buyer receives a

More information

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary

Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary Trends in Affordable Home Ownership in Calgary 2006 July www.calgary.ca Call 3-1-1 PUBLISHING INFORMATION TITLE: AUTHOR: STATUS: TRENDS IN AFFORDABLE HOME OWNERSHIP CORPORATE ECONOMICS FINAL PRINTING DATE:

More information

The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s.

The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s. The purpose of the appraisal was to determine the value of this six that is located in the Town of St. Mary s. The subject property was originally acquired by Michael and Bonnie Etta Mattiussi in August

More information

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING

COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING COMPARISON OF THE LONG-TERM COST OF SHELTER ALLOWANCES AND NON-PROFIT HOUSING Prepared for The Fair Rental Policy Organization of Ontario By Clayton Research Associates Limited October, 1993 EXECUTIVE

More information

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report

How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report How to Read a Real Estate Appraisal Report Much of the private, corporate and public wealth of the world consists of real estate. The magnitude of this fundamental resource creates a need for informed

More information

Geographic Variations in Resale Housing Values Within a Metropolitan Area: An Example from Suburban Phoenix, Arizona

Geographic Variations in Resale Housing Values Within a Metropolitan Area: An Example from Suburban Phoenix, Arizona INTRODUCTION Geographic Variations in Resale Housing Values Within a Metropolitan Area: An Example from Suburban Phoenix, Arizona Diane Whalley and William J. Lowell-Britt The average cost of single family

More information

Using Hedonics to Create Land and Structure Price Indexes for the Ottawa Condominium Market

Using Hedonics to Create Land and Structure Price Indexes for the Ottawa Condominium Market Using Hedonics to Create Land and Structure Price Indexes for the Ottawa Condominium Market Kate Burnett Isaacs Statistics Canada May 21, 2015 Abstract: Statistics Canada is developing a New Condominium

More information

Re-sales Analyses - Lansink and MPAC

Re-sales Analyses - Lansink and MPAC Appendix G Re-sales Analyses - Lansink and MPAC Introduction Lansink Appraisal and Consulting released case studies on the impact of proximity to industrial wind turbines (IWTs) on sale prices for properties

More information

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL

IREDELL COUNTY 2015 APPRAISAL MANUAL STATISTICS AND THE APPRAISAL PROCESS INTRODUCTION Statistics offer a way for the appraiser to qualify many of the heretofore qualitative decisions which he has been forced to use in assigning values. In

More information

7224 Nall Ave Prairie Village, KS 66208

7224 Nall Ave Prairie Village, KS 66208 Real Results - Income Package 10/20/2014 TABLE OF CONTENTS SUMMARY RISK Summary 3 RISC Index 4 Location 4 Population and Density 5 RISC Influences 5 House Value 6 Housing Profile 7 Crime 8 Public Schools

More information

The Change of Urban-rural Income Gap in Hefei and Its Influence on Economic Development

The Change of Urban-rural Income Gap in Hefei and Its Influence on Economic Development 2017 2 nd International Conference on Education, Management and Systems Engineering (EMSE 2017) ISBN: 978-1-60595-466-0 The Change of Urban-rural Income Gap in Hefei and Its Influence on Economic Development

More information

The Improved Net Rate Analysis

The Improved Net Rate Analysis The Improved Net Rate Analysis A discussion paper presented at Massey School Seminar of Economics and Finance, 30 October 2013. Song Shi School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Palmerston North,

More information

A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County

A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County Resilient Neighborhoods Technical Reports and White Papers Resilient Neighborhoods Initiative 5-2014 A Model to Calculate the Supply of Affordable Housing in Polk County Jiangping Zhou Iowa State University,

More information

Estimating User Accessibility Benefits with a Housing Sales Hedonic Model

Estimating User Accessibility Benefits with a Housing Sales Hedonic Model Estimating User Accessibility Benefits with a Housing Sales Hedonic Model Michael Reilly Metropolitan Transportation Commission mreilly@mtc.ca.gov March 31, 2016 Words: 1500 Tables: 2 @ 250 words each

More information

Messung der Preise Schwerin, 16 June 2015 Page 1

Messung der Preise Schwerin, 16 June 2015 Page 1 New weighting schemes in the house price indices of the Deutsche Bundesbank How should we measure residential property prices to inform policy makers? Elena Triebskorn*, Section Business Cycle, Price and

More information

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force

3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force 3rd Meeting of the Housing Task Force September 26, 2018 World Bank, 1818 H St. NW, Washington, DC MC 10-100 Linking Housing Comparisons Across Countries and Regions 1 Linking Housing Comparisons Across

More information

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data

Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Data Note 1/2018 Private sector rents in UK cities: analysis of Zoopla rental listings data Mark Livingston, Nick Bailey and Christina Boididou UBDC April 2018 Introduction The private rental sector (PRS)

More information

Regional Housing Trends

Regional Housing Trends Regional Housing Trends A Look at Price Aggregates Department of Economics University of Missouri at Saint Louis Email: rogerswil@umsl.edu January 27, 2011 Why are Housing Price Aggregates Important? Shelter

More information

EXPLANATION OF MARKET MODELING IN THE CURRENT KANSAS CAMA SYSTEM

EXPLANATION OF MARKET MODELING IN THE CURRENT KANSAS CAMA SYSTEM EXPLANATION OF MARKET MODELING IN THE CURRENT KANSAS CAMA SYSTEM I have been asked on numerous occasions to provide a lay man s explanation of the market modeling system of CAMA. I do not claim to be an

More information

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale

Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale Ad-valorem and Royalty Licensing under Decreasing Returns to Scale Athanasia Karakitsiou 2, Athanasia Mavrommati 1,3 2 Department of Business Administration, Educational Techological Institute of Serres,

More information

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY FEBRUARY 28, 2014 Metropolitan Council s Forecasts Methodology Long-range forecasts at Metropolitan Council are updated at least once per decade. Population,

More information

Sorting based on amenities and income

Sorting based on amenities and income Sorting based on amenities and income Mark van Duijn Jan Rouwendal m.van.duijn@vu.nl Department of Spatial Economics (Work in progress) Seminar Utrecht School of Economics 25 September 2013 Projects o

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2015, Volume 30 Volume Author/Editor: Martin Eichenbaum and Jonathan

More information

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area

Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Completed by: Will Dunning Inc. For: Trinity Diversified North America Limited February 2009 Housing as an Investment Greater Toronto Area Overview We are

More information

Efficiency in the California Real Estate Labor Market

Efficiency in the California Real Estate Labor Market American Journal of Economics and Business Administration 3 (4): 589-595, 2011 ISSN 1945-5488 2011 Science Publications Efficiency in the California Real Estate Labor Market Dirk Yandell School of Business

More information

Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016

Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016 Luxury Residences Report 2nd Half 2016 YEAR XIII No. 2 March 2017 1 Luxury Residences Report 2 nd Half 2016 Introduction Introduction and methodology 2 Luxury Residences Report 2 nd Half 2016 Introduction

More information

CABARRUS COUNTY 2016 APPRAISAL MANUAL

CABARRUS COUNTY 2016 APPRAISAL MANUAL STATISTICS AND THE APPRAISAL PROCESS PREFACE Like many of the technical aspects of appraising, such as income valuation, you have to work with and use statistics before you can really begin to understand

More information

AVM Validation. Evaluating AVM performance

AVM Validation. Evaluating AVM performance AVM Validation Evaluating AVM performance The responsible use of Automated Valuation Models in any application begins with a thorough understanding of the models performance in absolute and relative terms.

More information

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts?

How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts? Tulane Economics Working Paper Series How Did Foreclosures Affect Property Values in Georgia School Districts? James Alm Department of Economics Tulane University New Orleans, LA jalm@tulane.edu Robert

More information

Report on the methodology of house price indices

Report on the methodology of house price indices Frankfurt am Main, 16 February 2015 Report on the methodology of house price indices Owing to newly available data sources for weighting from the 2011 Census of buildings and housing and the data on the

More information

The Impact of Urban Growth on Affordable Housing:

The Impact of Urban Growth on Affordable Housing: The Impact of Urban Growth on Affordable Housing: An Economic Analysis Chris Bruce, Ph.D. and Marni Plunkett October 2000 Project funding provided by: P.O. Box 6572, Station D Calgary, Alberta, CANADA

More information

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership

Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Well Worth Saving: How the New Deal Safeguarded Home Ownership Volume Author/Editor: Price V.

More information

The calculation of inter-regional PPPs, or linking factors, for housing services is complicated by three factors:

The calculation of inter-regional PPPs, or linking factors, for housing services is complicated by three factors: Linking the regions: the case of housing 1- Introduction The calculation of inter-regional PPPs, or linking factors, for housing services is complicated by three factors: the various ICP regions have employed

More information

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore

The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore The Effects of Housing Price Changes on the Distribution of Housing Wealth in Singapore Joy Chan Yuen Yee & Liu Yunhua Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Nanyang Avenue, Singapore

More information

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly

A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly Submitted on 16/Sept./2010 Article ID: 1923-7529-2011-01-53-07 Judy Hsu and Henry Wang A Note on the Efficiency of Indirect Taxes in an Asymmetric Cournot Oligopoly Judy Hsu Department of International

More information

Chapter 37. The Appraiser's Cost Approach INTRODUCTION

Chapter 37. The Appraiser's Cost Approach INTRODUCTION Chapter 37 The Appraiser's Cost Approach INTRODUCTION The cost approach for estimating current market value starts with the recognition that a parcel of real estate contains two components - the land and

More information

Determinants of residential property valuation

Determinants of residential property valuation Determinants of residential property valuation Author: Ioana Cocos Coordinator: Prof. Univ. Dr. Ana-Maria Ciobanu Abstract: The aim of this thesis is to understand and know in depth the factors that cause

More information

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham

The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 1 The Effect of Relative Size on Housing Values in Durham Durham Research Paper Michael Ni TheEffectofRelativeSizeonHousingValuesinDurham 2 Introduction Real

More information

Volume URL:

Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Capital Formation in Residential Real Estate: Trends and Prospects Volume Author/Editor:

More information

RESOLUTION NO ( R)

RESOLUTION NO ( R) RESOLUTION NO. 2013-06- 088 ( R) A RESOLUTION OF THE CITY COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF McKINNEY, TEXAS, APPROVING THE LAND USE ASSUMPTIONS FOR THE 2012-2013 ROADWAY IMPACT FEE UPDATE WHEREAS, per Texas Local

More information

GENERAL ASSESSMENT DEFINITIONS

GENERAL ASSESSMENT DEFINITIONS 21st Century Appraisals, Inc. GENERAL ASSESSMENT DEFINITIONS Ad Valorem tax. A tax levied in proportion to the value of the thing(s) being taxed. Exclusive of exemptions, use-value assessment laws, and

More information

Proving Depreciation

Proving Depreciation Institute for Professionals in Taxation 40 th Annual Property Tax Symposium Tucson, Arizona Proving Depreciation Presentation Concepts and Content: Kathy G. Spletter, ASA Stancil & Co. Irving, Texas kathy.spletter@stancilco.com

More information

Objectives of Housing Task Force: Some Background

Objectives of Housing Task Force: Some Background 2 nd Meeting of the Housing Task Force March 12, 2018 World Bank, Washington, DC Objectives of Housing Task Force: Some Background Background What are the goals of ICP comparisons of housing services?

More information

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY JUNE 14, 2017

METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY JUNE 14, 2017 METROPOLITAN COUNCIL S FORECASTS METHODOLOGY JUNE 14, 2017 Metropolitan Council s Forecasts Methodology Long-range forecasts at Metropolitan Council are updated at least once per decade. Population, households

More information

Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions

Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions Goods and Services Tax and Mortgage Costs of Australian Credit Unions Author Liu, Benjamin, Huang, Allen Published 2012 Journal Title The Empirical Economics Letters Copyright Statement 2012 Rajshahi University.

More information

2. The, and Act, also known as FIRREA, requires that states set standards for all appraisers.

2. The, and Act, also known as FIRREA, requires that states set standards for all appraisers. CHAPTER 4 SHORT-ANSWER QUESTIONS 1. An appraisal is an or of value. 2. The, and Act, also known as FIRREA, requires that states set standards for all appraisers. 3. Value in real estate is the "present

More information

Demonstration Properties for the TAUREAN Residential Valuation System

Demonstration Properties for the TAUREAN Residential Valuation System Demonstration Properties for the TAUREAN Residential Valuation System Taurean has provided a set of four sample subject properties to demonstrate many of the valuation system s features and capabilities.

More information

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. Durability and Monopoly Author(s): R. H. Coase Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1 (Apr., 1972), pp. 143-149 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/725018

More information

Intangibles CHAPTER CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to:

Intangibles CHAPTER CHAPTER OBJECTIVES. After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to: CHAPTER Intangibles CHAPTER OBJECTIVES After careful study of this chapter, you will be able to: 1. Explain the accounting alternatives for intangibles. 2. Record the amortization or impairment of intangibles.

More information

School Quality and Property Values. In Greenville, South Carolina

School Quality and Property Values. In Greenville, South Carolina Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics Working Paper WP 423 April 23 School Quality and Property Values In Greenville, South Carolina Kwame Owusu-Edusei and Molly Espey Clemson University Public

More information

The Relationship Between Micro Spatial Conditions and Behaviour Problems in Housing Areas: A Case Study of Vandalism

The Relationship Between Micro Spatial Conditions and Behaviour Problems in Housing Areas: A Case Study of Vandalism The Relationship Between Micro Spatial Conditions and Behaviour Problems in Housing Areas: A Case Study of Vandalism Dr. Faisal Hamid, RIBA Hamid Associates, Architecture and Urban Design Consultants Baghdad,

More information

Use of Comparables. Claims Prevention Bulletin [CP-17-E] March 1996

Use of Comparables. Claims Prevention Bulletin [CP-17-E] March 1996 March 1996 The use of comparables arises almost daily for all appraisers. especially those engaged in residential practice, where appraisals are being prepared for mortgage underwriting purposes. That

More information

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model

An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model An overview of the real estate market the Fisher-DiPasquale-Wheaton model 13 January 2011 1 Real Estate Market What is real estate? How big is the real estate sector? How does the market for the use of

More information

Owner-Occupied Housing in the Norwegian HICP

Owner-Occupied Housing in the Norwegian HICP Owner-Occupied Housing in the Norwegian HICP Paper written for the 2009 Ottawa Group Conference in Neuchâtel, Switzerland, 27-29 May 2009. Ingvild Johansen ingvild.johansen@ssb.no Ragnhild Nygaard ragnhild.nygaard@ssb.no

More information

14 September 2015 MARKET ANALYTICS AND SCENARIO FORECASTING UNIT. JOHN LOOS: HOUSEHOLD AND PROPERTY SECTOR STRATEGIST

14 September 2015 MARKET ANALYTICS AND SCENARIO FORECASTING UNIT. JOHN LOOS: HOUSEHOLD AND PROPERTY SECTOR STRATEGIST 14 September 2015 MARKET ANALYTICS AND SCENARIO FORECASTING UNIT JOHN LOOS: HOUSEHOLD AND PROPERTY SECTOR STRATEGIST 087-328 0151 john.loos@fnb.co.za THEO SWANEPOEL: PROPERTY MARKET ANALYST 087-328 0157

More information

Chapter 12 Changes Since This is just a brief and cursory comparison. More analysis will be done at a later date.

Chapter 12 Changes Since This is just a brief and cursory comparison. More analysis will be done at a later date. Chapter 12 Changes Since 1986 This approach to Fiscal Analysis was first done in 1986 for the City of Anoka. It was the first of its kind and was recognized by the National Science Foundation (NSF). Geographic

More information

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS Box EURO AREA HOUSE PRICES AND THE RENT COMPONENT OF THE HICP In the euro area, as in many other economies, expenditures on buying a house or flat are not incorporated directly into consumer price indices,

More information

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373

EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 29.11.2008 EN Official Journal of the European Union L 320/373 INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARD 3 Business combinations OBJECTIVE 1 The objective of this IFRS is to specify the financial reporting

More information

Technical Description of the Freddie Mac House Price Index

Technical Description of the Freddie Mac House Price Index Technical Description of the Freddie Mac House Price Index 1. Introduction Freddie Mac publishes the monthly index values of the Freddie Mac House Price Index (FMHPI SM ) each quarter. Index values are

More information

A Quantitative Approach to Gentrification: Determinants of Gentrification in U.S. Cities,

A Quantitative Approach to Gentrification: Determinants of Gentrification in U.S. Cities, A Quantitative Approach to Gentrification: Determinants of Gentrification in U.S. Cities, 1970-2010 Richard W. Martin, Department of Insurance, Legal, Studies, and Real Estate, Terry College of Business,

More information

Business Valuation More Art Than Science

Business Valuation More Art Than Science Business Valuation More Art Than Science One of the more difficult aspects of business planning is business valuation. It is also one of the more important aspects. While owners of closely held businesses

More information

Effects of Zoning on Residential Option Value. Jonathan C. Young RESEARCH PAPER

Effects of Zoning on Residential Option Value. Jonathan C. Young RESEARCH PAPER Effects of Zoning on Residential Option Value By Jonathan C. Young RESEARCH PAPER 2004-12 Jonathan C. Young Department of Economics West Virginia University Business and Economics BOX 41 Morgantown, WV

More information

Chapter 11 Investments in Noncurrent Operating Assets Utilization and Retirement

Chapter 11 Investments in Noncurrent Operating Assets Utilization and Retirement Chapter 11 Investments in Noncurrent Operating Assets Utilization and Retirement 1. The annual depreciation expense 2. The depletion of natural resources 3. The changes in estimates and methods in the

More information

LKAS 17 Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 17

LKAS 17 Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 17 Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 17 Leases CONTENTS SRI LANKA ACCOUNTING STANDARD LKAS 17 LEASES paragraphs OBJECTIVE 1 SCOPE 2 DEFINITIONS 4 CLASSIFICATION OF LEASES 7 LEASES IN THE FINANCIAL STATEMENTS

More information

Economic Impact of Commercial Multi-Unit Residential Property Transactions in Toronto, Calgary and Vancouver,

Economic Impact of Commercial Multi-Unit Residential Property Transactions in Toronto, Calgary and Vancouver, Economic Impact of Commercial Multi-Unit Residential Property Transactions in Toronto, Calgary and Vancouver, 2006-2008 SEPTEMBER 2009 Economic Impact of Commercial Multi-Unit Residential Property Transactions

More information

The Impact of Using. Market-Value to Replacement-Cost. Ratios on Housing Insurance in Toledo Neighborhoods

The Impact of Using. Market-Value to Replacement-Cost. Ratios on Housing Insurance in Toledo Neighborhoods The Impact of Using Market-Value to Replacement-Cost Ratios on Housing Insurance in Toledo Neighborhoods February 12, 1999 Urban Affairs Center The University of Toledo Toledo, OH 43606-3390 Prepared by

More information

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount?

Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount? Can the coinsurance effect explain the diversification discount? ABSTRACT Rong Guo Columbus State University Mansi and Reeb (2002) document that the coinsurance effect can fully explain the diversification

More information

THE EFFECT OF PROXIMITY TO PUBLIC TRANSIT ON PROPERTY VALUES

THE EFFECT OF PROXIMITY TO PUBLIC TRANSIT ON PROPERTY VALUES THE EFFECT OF PROXIMITY TO PUBLIC TRANSIT ON PROPERTY VALUES Public transit networks are essential to the functioning of a city. When purchasing a property, some buyers will try to get as close as possible

More information

Working Papers. Research Department WORKING PAPER NO. 99-9/R MEASURING HOUSING SERVICES INFLATION. Theodore M. Crone Leonard I. Nakamura Richard Voith

Working Papers. Research Department WORKING PAPER NO. 99-9/R MEASURING HOUSING SERVICES INFLATION. Theodore M. Crone Leonard I. Nakamura Richard Voith FEDERALRESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA Ten Independence Mall Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106-1574 (215) 574-6428, www.phil.frb.org Working Papers Research Department WORKING PAPER NO. 99-9/R MEASURING HOUSING

More information

While the United States experienced its larg

While the United States experienced its larg Jamie Davenport The Effect of Demand and Supply factors on the Affordability of Housing Jamie Davenport 44 I. Introduction While the United States experienced its larg est period of economic growth in

More information

A Comparison of Downtown and Suburban Office Markets. Nikhil Patel. B.S. Finance & Management Information Systems, 1999 University of Arizona

A Comparison of Downtown and Suburban Office Markets. Nikhil Patel. B.S. Finance & Management Information Systems, 1999 University of Arizona A Comparison of Downtown and Suburban Office Markets by Nikhil Patel B.S. Finance & Management Information Systems, 1999 University of Arizona Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies & Planning in

More information

International Accounting Standard 17 Leases. Objective. Scope. Definitions IAS 17

International Accounting Standard 17 Leases. Objective. Scope. Definitions IAS 17 International Accounting Standard 17 Leases Objective 1 The objective of this Standard is to prescribe, for lessees and lessors, the appropriate accounting policies and disclosure to apply in relation

More information

Luxury Residences Report First Half 2017

Luxury Residences Report First Half 2017 Luxury Residences Report First Half 2017 YEAR XIV n. 1 October 2017 1 Luxury Residences Report: First Half 2017 Introduction Introduction and methodology 2 Luxury Residences Report: First Half 2017 Introduction

More information

Metro Boston Perfect Fit Parking Initiative

Metro Boston Perfect Fit Parking Initiative Metro Boston Perfect Fit Parking Initiative Phase 1 Technical Memo Report by the Metropolitan Area Planning Council February 2017 1 About MAPC The Metropolitan Area Planning Council (MAPC) is the regional

More information

RESIDENTIAL MARKET ANALYSIS

RESIDENTIAL MARKET ANALYSIS RESIDENTIAL MARKET ANALYSIS CLANCY TERRY RMLS Student Fellow Master of Real Estate Development Candidate Oregon and national housing markets both demonstrated shifting trends in the first quarter of 2015

More information

V2 = ( V1 - v1 ) V2 = V1 + ( v2 - ) (v2 - v1) is the net inventory change between the two time periods, and the rate of net inventory change is

V2 = ( V1 - v1 ) V2 = V1 + ( v2 - ) (v2 - v1) is the net inventory change between the two time periods, and the rate of net inventory change is A IMPLIFIED URBAN HOUING INVENTORY MODEL - WITH PRACTICAL APPLICATION Ko Ching hih, U.. Department of Housing Urban Development I. Introduction ince 1950, the Bureau of the Census has established a standard

More information

acuitas, inc. s survey of fair value audit deficiencies August 31, 2014 pcaob inspections methodology description of a deficiency

acuitas, inc. s survey of fair value audit deficiencies August 31, 2014 pcaob inspections methodology description of a deficiency August 31, 2014 home executive summary audit deficiencies improve pcaob inspections methodology description of a deficiency audit deficiency trends fvm deficiencies description of fair value measurement

More information

Relationship of age and market value of office buildings in Tirana City

Relationship of age and market value of office buildings in Tirana City Relationship of age and market value of office buildings in Tirana City Phd. Elfrida SHEHU Polytechnic University of Tirana Civil Engineering Department of Civil Engineering Faculty Tirana, Albania elfridaal@yahoo.com

More information

Assessment-To-Sales Ratio Study for Division III Equalization Funding: 1999 Project Summary. State of Delaware Office of the Budget

Assessment-To-Sales Ratio Study for Division III Equalization Funding: 1999 Project Summary. State of Delaware Office of the Budget Assessment-To-Sales Ratio Study for Division III Equalization Funding: 1999 Project Summary prepared for the State of Delaware Office of the Budget by Edward C. Ratledge Center for Applied Demography and

More information

Evaluation of Vertical Equity in Residential Property Assessments in the Lake Oswego and West Linn Areas

Evaluation of Vertical Equity in Residential Property Assessments in the Lake Oswego and West Linn Areas Portland State University PDXScholar Center for Urban Studies Publications and Reports Center for Urban Studies 2-1988 Evaluation of Vertical Equity in Residential Property Assessments in the Lake Oswego

More information

7829 Glenwood Avenue Canal Winchester, Ohio November 19,2013

7829 Glenwood Avenue Canal Winchester, Ohio November 19,2013 7829 Glenwood Avenue Canal Winchester, Ohio 43110 614-920-1425 November 19,2013 Technical Director File Reference Number 2013-270 Financial Standards Accounting Board 401 Merritt 7 Norwalk, Connecticut

More information

BUSI 398 Residential Property Guided Case Study

BUSI 398 Residential Property Guided Case Study BUSI 398 Residential Property Guided Case Study PURPOSE AND SCOPE The Residential Property Guided Case Study course BUSI 398 is intended to give the real estate appraisal student a working knowledge of

More information

Residential September 2010

Residential September 2010 Residential September 2010 Karl L. Guntermann Fred E. Taylor Professor of Real Estate Adam Nowak Research Associate For the first time since March, house prices turned down slightly in August (-2 percent)

More information

REPORT. Research. Determining a Fair Rental Arrangement. Introduction. Types of Rental Arrangements. Kenneth W.. Paxton and Michael E.

REPORT. Research. Determining a Fair Rental Arrangement. Introduction. Types of Rental Arrangements. Kenneth W.. Paxton and Michael E. REPORT Research Number 110 - Summer 2001 Determining a Fair Rental Arrangement Kenneth W.. Paxton and Michael E. Salassi Introduction Most of the crop agriculture in Louisiana is produced on rented land.

More information

Auditing PP&E, Including Leases

Auditing PP&E, Including Leases Auditing PP&E, Including Leases Learning Objectives Discuss typical audit risks and special considerations. Tailor an audit plan to assessed audit risk. Explain key controls related to PP&E. Describe lease

More information